Skip to main content
Log in

A quantitative analysis of risk-sharing agreements with patient support programs for improving medication adherence

  • Published:
Health Care Management Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Medication adherence is a challenge for patients, drugmakers, and payers. To promote adherence, some payers adopt a form of pay-for-success value-based risk-sharing agreements. Drugmakers reduce prices for meaningful improvement in adherence and share patient information and resources with payers; as a return, payers run patient support programs and put drugs on a tier with lower copays. We use a game-theoretic approach to investigate the optimal program effect and the optimal prices with and without improvement in adherence, measured by Proportion of Days Covered, under such an agreement. Since negotiation power impacts how prices are determined, we consider several pricing settings: the payer or the drugmaker sets both prices or sets one price simultaneously or sequentially. Although a discount for improved adherence tends to promote adherence, it may not always be achievable nor guarantees better adherence. The drugmaker with strong negotiation power can align its interest with social welfare but the payer may not. The payer with strong negotiation power can improve more adherence than the drugmaker. Balanced negotiation power contributes either the most or the least to adherence depending on contract form and decision sequence. Although cost-sharing by the drugmaker expects to increase program efforts, it may not be true. We find that the policymaker prefers different levels of cost-sharing under different pricing settings. The payer may have a first-mover advantage when setting the price without improved adherence; the drugmaker, however, does not have such an advantage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Sabaté E (2003) Adherence to long-term therapies: evidence for action. World Health Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  2. Ho PM, Bryson CL, Rumsfeld JS (2009) Medication adherence: its importance in cardiovascular outcomes. Circulation. 119:3028–3035. https://doi.org/10.1161/CIRCULATIONAHA.108.768986

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Brown MT, Bussell JK (2011) Medication adherence: WHO cares? Mayo Clin Proc 86:304–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Cadarette SM, Burden AM (2010) Measuring and improving adherence to osteoporosis pharmacotherapy. Curr Opin Rheumatol 22:397–403. https://doi.org/10.1097/BOR.0b013e32833ac7fe

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Pharmacy Times (2015) Do You Know the Difference Between These Adherence Measures? https://www.pharmacytimes.com/view/pharmacy-students-discuss-the-future-of-the-role-of-the-pharmacist. Accessed Aug 27 2021

  6. Pharmacy Quality Alliance (2021) PQA Adherence Measures. https://www.pqaalliance.org/adherence-measures. Accessed August 27 2021

  7. Lestra M, Nwankwo C, Bird Y, Moraros J (2018) Primary nonadherence to chronic disease medications: a meta-analysis. Patient Prefer Adherence 12:721–731. https://doi.org/10.2147/PPA.S161151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Jimmy B, Jose J (2011) Patient medication adherence: measures in daily practice. Oman Medical Journal 26:155–159. https://doi.org/10.5001/omj.2011.38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. U.S. Food & Drug Administration (2016) Why You Need to Take Your Medications as Prescribed or Instructed. https://www.fda.gov/drugs/special-features/why-you-need-take-your-medications-prescribed-or-instructed. Accessed Apr 23 2021

  10. Yu JS, Chin L, Oh J, Farias J (2017) Performance-based risk-sharing arrangements for pharmaceutical products in the United States: a systematic review. Journal of Managed Care & Specialty Pharmacy 23:1028–1040

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. NEHI (2017) Rewarding results: moving forward on value-based contracing for biopharmaceuticals. N.f.E.i.H. Innovation

  12. Pagliarulo N (2018) Pushing 'value,' Harvard Pilgrim tests outcomes deals. https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/harvard-pilgrim-astrazeneca-symbicort-value-contract/521659/. Accessed Apr 28 2021

  13. Garrison LP, Carlson JJ, Bajaj PS, Towse A, Neumann PJ, Sullivan SD, Westrick K, Dubois RW (2015) Private sector risk-sharing agreements in the United States: trends, barriers, and prospects. Am J Manag Care 21:632–640

    Google Scholar 

  14. Managed Healthcare Executive (2017) Value-based drug contracting shifts risk to manufacturers. https://www.managedhealthcareexecutive.com/view/jeffrey-brenner-is-leaving-unitedhealth-to-return-to-primary-care-roots. Accessed 30 Jul 2020

  15. Palmer S (2017) Amgen strikes Enbrel 'outcomes' contract with Harvard Pilgrim. https://www.fiercepharma.com/pharma/amgen-strikes-outcomes-contract-for-enbrel-as-biosimilar-competition-lurks. Accessed May 05 2021

  16. Kannarkat JT, Good CB, Kelly E, Parekh N (2020) Examining Misaligned Incentives for Payers and Manufacturers in Value-Based Pharmaceutical Contracts. Journal of Managed Care & Specialty Pharmacy. 26:63–66. https://doi.org/10.18553/jmcp.2020.26.1.63

  17. Harvard Pilgrim Health Care (2017) Harvard Pilgrim signs value-based contract with Eli Lilly & Company for its osteoporosis drug, Forteo. https://www.harvardpilgrim.org/public/news-detail?nt=HPH_News_C&nid=1471912468207#:~:text=Harvard%20Pilgrim%20Signs%20Value%2Dbased,for%20its%20Osteoporosis%20drug%2C%20Forteo&text=Wellesley%2C%20MA%20(February%2022%2C,patients'%20adherence%20to%20the%20drug. Accessed 02 July 2020

  18. STAT (2016) Big Pharma’s big push to get patients to take their meds. https://www.statnews.com/2016/02/04/big-pharma-medication-adherence/. Accessed 25 Mar 2020

  19. van Maren MA, Wyers CE, Driessen JHM, Visser JV, de Vries F, van de Wijdeven K, Gevers S, Lems WF, Emmelot-Vonk MH, van den Bergh JPW (2019) Two-year persistence with teriparatide improved significantly after introduction of an educational and motivational support program. Osteoporos Int 30:1837–1844. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00198-019-05052-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Morgan S, Daw J, Thomson P (2013) International best practices for negotiating 'reimbursement contracts' with price rebates from pharmaceutical companies. Health Aff 32:771–777

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Kim AE, Choi DH, Chang J, Kim SH (2020) Performance-based risk-sharing arrangements (PBRSA): is it a solution to increase bang for the Buck for pharmaceutical reimbursement strategy for our nation and around the world? Clinical Drug Investigation 40:1107–1113. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40261-020-00972-w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Pollack A (2009) Drug deals tie prices to how well patients do. https://www.nytimes.com/2009/04/23/business/23cigna.html. Accessed May 05 2021

  23. Biopharma Dive (2017) Can value-based deals work if patients don't take the drug? https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/adherence-value-based-deal-payment-patient-outcomes/442449/. Accessed 15 Sep 2010

  24. Barros PP (2011) The simple economics of risk-sharing agreements between the NHS and the pharmaceutical industry. Health Econ 20:461–470. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Antonanzas F, Juarez-Castello CA, Rodriguez-Ibeas R (2011) Should health authorities offer risk-sharing contracts to pharmaceutical firms? A theoretical approach. Health Economics, Policy and Law 6:391–403. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744133111000016

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Zaric GS, Xie B (2009) The impact of two pharmaceutical risk sharing agreements on pricing, promotion, and net health benefits. Value Health 12:838–845. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1524-4733.2009.00510.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Mahjoub R, Ødegaard F, Zaric G (2018) Evaluation of a pharmaceutical risk-sharing agreement when patients are screened for the probability of success. Health Econ 27:e15–e25. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Critchley GJ, Zaric GS (2019) The impact of pharmaceutical marketing on market access, treatment coverage, pricing, and social welfare. Health Econ 28:1035–1051. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Ayer T, Alagoz O, Stout NK, Burnside ES (2016) Heterogeneity in women’s adherence and its role in optimal breast cancer screening policies. Manag Sci 62:1339–1362. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Mason JE, England DA, Denton BT, Smith SA, Kurt M, Shah ND (2012) Optimizing statin treatment decisions for diabetes patients in the presence of uncertain future adherence. Med Decis Mak 32:154–166. https://doi.org/10.1177/0272989X11404076

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. McCoy JH (2014) Clinic capacity management: planning treatment programs that incorporate adherence. Producton and Operations Management 23:1–18. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12036

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Lee K, Fader P, Hardie B (2007) How to Project Patient Persistency Foresight: The International Journal of Applied Forecasting. 8:31–35

  33. Neslin S, Rhoads E, Wolfson P (2009) A Model and Empirical Analysis of Patient Compliance and Persistence in Pharmaceuticals. Unpublished Manuscript: Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College

  34. Taylor T (2002) Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Manag Sci 48:992–1007. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.8.992.168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Cachon GP, Lariviere MA (2005) Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: strengths and limitations. Manag Sci 51:30–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Krishnan H, Kapuscinski R, Butz D (2004) Coordinating contracts for decentralized supply chains with retailer promotional effort. Manag Sci 50:48–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Schectman JM, Nadkarni MM, Voss JD (2002) The association between diabetes metabolic control and drug adherence in an indigent population. Diabetes Care 25:1015–1021. https://doi.org/10.2337/diacare.25.6.1015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Ho PM, Rumsfeld JS, Masoudi FA (2006) Effect of medication nonadherence on hospitalization and mortality among patients with diabetes mellitus. Arch Intern Med 166:1836–1841. https://doi.org/10.1001/archinte.166.17.1836

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Polonsky WH, Henry RR (2016) Poor medication adherence in type 2 diabetes: recognizing the scope of the problem and its key contributors. Patient Prefer Adherence. 10:1299–1307. https://doi.org/10.2147/PPA.S106821

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Lin LK, Sun Y, Heng BH, Chew DEK, Chong PH (2017) Medication adherence and glycemic control among newly diagnosed diabetes patients. BMJ Open Diab Res Care 5:1–9. https://doi.org/10.1136/bmjdrc-2017-000429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Chan D, Chang CH, Lim L (2016) Association between teriparatide treatment persistence and adherence, and fracture incidence in Taiwan: analysis using the National Health Insurance Research Database. Osteoporos International 27:2855–2865. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00198-016-3611-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Hazel-Fernandez L, Louder AM, Foster SA (2013) Association of teriparatide adherence and persistence with clinical and economic outcomes in Medicare part D recipients: a retrospective cohort study. BMC Musculoskelet Disord 14:1–17. https://doi.org/10.1186/1471-2474-14-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Morisky DE, Ang A, Krousel-Wood M, Ward HJ (2008) Predictive validity of a medication adherence measure in an outpatient setting. The Journal of Clinical Hypertension 10:348–354. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1751-7176.2008.07572.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Rabenda V, Mertens R, Fabri V, Vanoverloop J, Sumkay F, Vannecke C, Deswaef A, Verpooten GA, Reginster JY (2008) Adherence to bisphosphonates therapy and hip fracture risk in osteoporotic women. Osteoporos Int 19:811–818. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00198-007-0506-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. So KC, Tang CS (2000) Modeling the impact of an outcome-oriented reimbursement policy on clinic, patients, and pharmaceutical firms. Manag Sci 46:875–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Durden E, Pinto L, Lopez-Gonzalez L, Juneau P, Barron R (2017) Two-year persistence and compliance with osteoporosis therapies among postmenopausal women in a commercially insured population in the United States. Arch Osteoporos 12:22. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11657-017-0316-5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Bala R, Bhardwaj P (2010) Detailing vs. direct-to-consumer advertising in the prescription pharmaceutical industry. Manag Sci 56:148–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Biopharma Dive (2017) Harvard Pilgrim bets on value-based drug payments with new deals. https://www.biopharmadive.com/news/harvard-pilgrim-value-based-amgen-eli-lilly/436673/. Accessed 02 Jul 2020

  49. Zhang H, Zaric GS, Huang T (2011) Optimal design of a pharmaceutical price-volume agreement under asymmetric information about expected market size. Prod Oper Manag 20:334–346. https://doi.org/10.1111/J.1937-5956.2011.01219.X

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Levaggi R (2014) Pricing schemes for new drugs: a welfare analysis. Soc Sci Med 102:69–73. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socscimed.2013.11.048

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Brekke K, Konigbauer I, Straume O (2007) Reference pricing of pharmaceuticals. J Health Econ 26:613–642. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2006.11.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Smith D, Pagel C, Utley M, Gallivan S (2008) Quantifying the impact of non-adherence to drug therapy: a technical note concerning an application of a branch and bound algorithm. Health Care Manage Sci 11:302–305. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10729-007-9047-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Neumann P, Chambers J, Simon F, Meckley L (2011) Risk-sharing arrangements that link payment for drugs to health outcomes are proving hard to implement. Health Aff 30:2329–2337. https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.2010.1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors contributed to the study conception and design. Material preparation, model development, and analysis were performed by Hui Zhang and Tao Huang. The literature review was prepared by Tao Yan. The first draft of the manuscript was written by Hui Zhang and all authors commented on previous versions of the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hui Zhang.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Fig. 1
figure 1

A classification scheme for patients receiving treatment

Table 1 Summary of notation
Fig. 2
figure 2

The optimal program effect e for combinations of p1 and p2

Fig. 3
figure 3

The change of hD(p1, p2) and hP(p1, p2) w.r.t prices

Fig. 4
figure 4

The optimal program effect under different pricing settings. a With respect to the unit health benefit bb With respect to the expected refill rate rc With respect to the marginal program cost kd With respect to the baseline Le With respect to cost-sharing t.

Fig. 5
figure 5

The impact of cost-sharing t on the optimal prices

Fig. 6
figure 6

The impact of cost-sharing t on both parties’ utilities under different pricing settings

Fig. 7
figure 7

The optimal social welfare under different pricing settings. a With respect to the unit health benefit bb With respect to the expected refill rate rc With respect to the marginal program cost kd With respect to the baseline Le With respect to cost-sharing t.

Appendix 2

1.1 Proof for Lemma 1

The FOC ofVP w.r.t. e is:

$$\frac{dV_P}{de}=\left(b-{p}_2\right)\left(1-r\right)F\left(1-e\right)- tke-\left({p}_1-{p}_2\right)\left(1-r\right)F\left(L-e\right)+\left({p}_1-{p}_2\right)\left[L\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left(L-e\right)=0.$$

The second derivative of VP w.r.t. e is:

$$\frac{d^2{V}_P}{de^2}=-\left(b-{p}_2\right)\left(1-r\right)f^{\prime}\left(1-e\right)- tk+\left({p}_1-{p}_2\right)\left(1-r\right)f^{\prime}\left(L-e\right)-\left({p}_1-{p}_2\right)\left[L\left(1-r\right)+r\right]{f}^{\prime}\left(L-e\right).$$

Let eP be the solution to\(\frac{dV_P}{de}=\)0. When a0 is from a uniform distribution U[0, 1], we have \({e}^P=\frac{b\left(1-r\right)+{p}_1r-{p}_2}{tk+\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)}\) and \(\frac{d^2{V}_P}{de^2}=\)tk − (b − p1)(1 − r).

If p1 < b + tk/(1 − r), then VP is concave in e; and the optimal effect is max(0,min(eP, L)). 0<eP<L when l1(p1) < p2 < l2(p1). If p1 > b + tk/(1 − r), then VPP is convex in e. e=0 if eP > L/2, e=L if eP < L/2, eis either 0 or L otherwise. If p1 = b + tk/(1 − r), then e= L if p2 < l2(p1), e= 0 if p2 > l2(p1), and eis any value ifp2 = l2(p1).

$$\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{rtk+\left(1-r\right)b-\left(1-r\right){p}_2}{{\left[ tk+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_1\right)\right]}^2}>0,\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}=-\frac{1}{tk+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_1\right)}<0$$

1.2 Proof for Lemma 3a)

\(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}=-{\int}_0^{L-e}\left[\left({a}_0+e\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0\le 0\), (and)

\(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}=-{\int}_{L-e}^{1-e}\left[\left({a}_0+e\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0-{\int}_{1-e}^1f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0<0\).

\(\frac{\partial {h}_P\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {e}^{\ast }}\frac{\partial {e}^{\ast }}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}\le 0\). Similarly, \(\frac{\partial {h}_P\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}\le 0\).

1.3 Proof for Lemma 3b)

Given p2, the drugmaker’s profit as a function of p1 has three segments, corresponding to e=0, eP and L, respectively. Since \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\), hD(p1, p2)increases with p1 for relatively small p1 (e=0). When e=L, \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}\)=0 and hD(p1, p2) is a constant. When e=eP, we have \(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {e}^P}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{rtk+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_2\right)}{{\left[\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk\right]}^2}\left(b\left(1-r\right)-\left(b\left(1-r\right)+k\right){e}^P\right)\).

Since \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}\)>0 and \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\), hD(p1, p2) always increases with p1 if b(1 − r) − (b(1 − r) + k)L > 0; it first increases then declines with p1 otherwise.

1.4 Proof for Lemma 3c)

Given p1, the first derivative of hD(p1, p2) w.r.t p2 is:

\(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}={\int}_{L-e}^{1-e}\left[\left({a}_0+e\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0+{\int}_{1-e}^1f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0+\frac{\partial e}{\partial {p}_2}\left[b\left(1-r\right)\left(1-e\right)- ke\right]\), where \({\int}_{L-e}^{1-e}\left[\left({a}_0+e\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0+{\int}_{1-e}^1f\left({a}_0\right){da}_0=\left(1-L\right)\left(r+\frac{\left(1-r\right)\left(1+L\right)}{2}\right)+e\)>0. In particular, when e = eP, \(\frac{\partial e}{\partial {p}_2}=-\frac{1}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\)<0 if (b − p1)(1 − r) + k>0. When e = 0ore = L, \(\frac{\partial e}{\partial {p}_2}=0\) and \(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}>0\). When e = eP, since b(1 − r)(1 − eP) − keP decreases with eP while eP decreases with p2, b(1 − r)(1 − eP) − keP increases with p2. \({e}^P=\frac{b\left(1-r\right)+{rp}_1}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\) at p2 = 0 so that b(1 − r)(1 − eP) − keP<0 at p2 = 0, and increases with p2 thereafter. That is, \(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}>0\) at p2 = 0 and the drugmaker’s profit increases with p2 from p2 = 0. As p2 rises, eP decreases and b(1 − r)(1 − eP) − keP increases so that \(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}\) may be reduced to 0 with eP<eS. When eP declines to 0, \(\frac{\partial {h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_2}=\frac{1}{2}\left(1-r\right)\left(1-{L}^2\right)+r\left(1-L\right)-\frac{b\left(1-r\right)}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\). If this value is negative, i.e., \({p}_1>b-\frac{2b}{\left(1-r\right)\left(1-{L}^2\right)+2r\left(1-L\right)}+\frac{tk}{1-r}\), then hD(p1, p2) is concave in p2; otherwise, it increases with p2 until eP=0.

1.5 Proof for Lemma 4a)

From hP(p1, p2)=0, we get a relationship between p1 and p2, denoted by p1 = g(p2), where g(p2) satisfies:

$$\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\left(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)\right)=0.$$

Since \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}=0\), we have \({g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)=-\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}{\left(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}\right)}^{-1}\)<0.

By deriving t on both sides of hP(p1, p2)=0, we have \(\frac{dg\left({p}_2\right)}{dt}=-\frac{\frac{{\partial V}_P}{\partial t}+\frac{{\partial V}_P}{\partial e}\frac{{\partial e}^P}{\partial t}}{\frac{{\partial V}_P}{{\partial p}_1}+\frac{{\partial V}_P}{\partial e}\frac{{\partial e}^P}{{\partial p}_1}}\) , where \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}=\frac{\partial {h}_P\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)}{\partial {p}_1}\)<0. Thus \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}<\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}\frac{\partial {V}_P/\partial {p}_1}{\partial {e}^P/\partial {p}_1}\)<0 because \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial t}<0,\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}<0,\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}<0,\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\). Thus, \(\frac{dg\left({p}_2\right)}{dt}\)<0 when e = eP and \(\frac{dg\left({p}_2\right)}{dt}\)=0 when e = 0. The same logic applies to g−1(p1).

1.6 Proof for Lemma 4b)

First, we consider hD(p1, p2) given p2. When e = 0, hD(p1, p2)=0 only if p1 ≤ 0; when e = L, hD(p1, p2) is a constant. Thus, the solution to hD(p1, p2)=0 must happen when e = eP. When e = eP, given p1, hD(p1, p2) first increases with and then decreases with p2. Thus, when hD(p1, p2)increases with p2, l(p2) has to be reduced for a higher p2; when hD(p1, p2)decreases with p2, l(p2)has to be increased for a higher p2.

By deriving t on both sides of hD(p1, p2)=0 given e = eP, we have \(\frac{dl\left({p}_2\right)}{dt}=-\frac{\frac{{\partial V}_D}{\partial t}+\frac{{\partial V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{{\partial e}^P}{\partial t}}{\frac{{\partial V}_D}{{\partial p}_1}+\frac{{\partial V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{{\partial e}^P}{{\partial p}_1}}\) , where \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\) because hD(p1, p2) increases with p1 at p1 = l(p2). Thus, \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}>\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}\frac{\partial {V}_D/\partial {p}_1}{\partial {e}^P/\partial {p}_1}\)>0 because \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial t}>0\), \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial t}<0\), \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}>0\), and \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\). Therefore, \(\frac{dl\left({p}_2\right)}{dt}\)<0. The same logic applies to l−1(p1).

1.7 Proof for Lemma 4c)

\({p}_1^D\left({p}_2\right)\) is obtained from the following FOC:

$$m=\frac{\left(1-r\right){\left(L-{e}^P\right)}^2}{2}+\left({e}^P+\left(1-{e}^P\right)r\right)\left(L-{e}^P\right)+\frac{rtk+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_2\right)}{{\left[\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk\right]}^2}\left(b\left(1-r\right)-\left(b\left(1-r\right)+k\right){e}^P\right)=0.$$

By deriving p2 on both sides, we have.

\(\frac{dp_1^D\left({p}_2\right)}{dp_2}=-\frac{\frac{\partial m}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial m}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}}{\frac{\partial m}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial m}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}}\), where \(\frac{\partial m}{\partial e}=-{e}^P-\left(1-{e}^P\right)r<0\), b(1 − r) − (b(1 − r) + k)eP<0, \(\frac{\partial m}{\partial {p}_2}>0,\frac{\partial m}{\partial {p}_1}<0\), \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}<0\). Thus, \(\frac{dp_1^D\left({p}_2\right)}{dp_2}\)>0.

\({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\) is obtained from the following FOC:

$$\left(1-L\right)\left(\frac{1}{2}\left(1-r\right)\left(1+L\right)+r\right)+{e}^P-\frac{b\left(1-r\right)-\left(b\left(1-r\right)+k\right){e}^P}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}=0.$$

By deriving p1for both sides, we have.

\(\left(1+\frac{b\left(1-r\right)+k}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\right)\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}-\left(1-r\right)\frac{b\left(1-r\right)-\left(b\left(1-r\right)+k\right){e}^P}{{\left[\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk\right]}^2}+\left(1+\frac{b\left(1-r\right)+k}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\right)\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dp_2^D}{dp_1}=0.\)Since \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}<0\), and \(\left(1+\frac{b\left(1-r\right)+k}{\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk}\right)\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}-\left(1-r\right)\frac{b\left(1-r\right)-\left(b\left(1-r\right)+k\right){e}^P}{{\left[\left(b-{p}_1\right)\left(1-r\right)+ tk\right]}^2}=\frac{r\beta k+r\left(1-r\right)b-\left(1-r\right){p}_2}{{\left[\beta k+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_1\right)\right]}^2}+\left(k+b\left(1-r\right)\right)\frac{r\beta k+\left(1-r\right)\left(2-r\right)b-2\left(1-r\right){p}_2+\left(1-r\right){p}_1r}{{\left[\beta k+\left(1-r\right)\left(b-{p}_1\right)\right]}^3}\). Thus, \(\frac{dp_2^D}{dp_1}\) p2 is uncertain.

1.8 Proof for case 1 (Proposition 1)

The payer’s problem is:

$$\underset{p_1,{p}_2}{\max }{h}_P\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)$$

s.t. hP≥ 0, hD≥ 0, and p1, p2 ≥ 0.

Since hP(p1, p2) decreases with p1and p2, the optimal prices should be the lowest possible feasible solution. When both prices are 0, hD(p1, p2)<0 if t < 1, making it infeasible. Thus, the prices have to be reduced until hD(p1, p2)=0. Otherwise, if hD(p1, p2)>0, then p1and p2 can be lowered without changing the program effect so that hP(p1, p2) is increased. Thus, hP(p1, p2) = VS.

From e = eP and hD(p1, p2)=0, we havep2 = l−1(p1), which is replaced into VP so that VP = HP(p1). Thus, \({H}_P^{\prime}\left({p}_1\right)=\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\left[\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}\right]=\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}\), where \(\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}\)satisfies\(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\left[\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}\right]=0\). Thus, \({H}_P^{\prime}\left({p}_1\right)=\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\left[\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dl^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{dp_1}\right]\). If \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}=0\), then eP = eS, i.e., \({p}_2=\frac{p_1\left[b\left(1-r\right)+ kr\right]+b\left(1-r\right)k\left(1-t\right)}{b\left(1-r\right)+k}\), which is replaced into VD so that \({\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{V}_D=\frac{p_1\left[b\left(1-r\right)+ kr\right]+b\left(1-r\right)k\left(1-t\right)}{b\left(1-r\right)+k}\left[{\int}_{L-{e}^S}^{1-{e}^S}\left[\left({a}_0+{e}^S\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right)d{a}_0+{e}^S\right]\\ {}+{p}_1{\int}_0^{L-{e}^S}\left[\left({a}_0+{e}^S\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right)d{a}_0-\left(1-t\right)\frac{k{\left({e}^S\right)}^2}{2}\\ {}=\frac{p_1\left[b\left(1-r\right)+ kr\right]}{b\left(1-r\right)+k}+{p}_1{\int}_0^{L-{e}^S}\left[\left({a}_0+{e}^S\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right)d{a}_0\\ {}+\frac{b\left(1-r\right)k\left(1-t\right)}{b\left(1-r\right)+k}\left[{\int}_{L-{e}^S}^{1-{e}^S}\left[\left({a}_0+{e}^S\right)\left(1-r\right)+r\right]f\left({a}_0\right)d{a}_0+{e}^S/2\right]\end{array}}\).

V D=0 only when t = 1 and p1=0. When t < 1 and p1=0, VD>0. Thus, to reduce VD to 0, p2 has to be lowed untilp2 = l−1(0)and the resulting program effect is larger than eS. Any combination of p1 and p2 = l−1(p1)generates a program effect larger than eS i.e., \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}<0\). Thus, \(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{d{l}^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)}{d{p}_1}={\left(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\right)}^{-1}\left[\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}\left(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\right)-\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\left(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}\right)\right]=\Big({}^{\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}}\left[\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}-\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}\right]>0\), and \({H}_P^{\prime}\left({p}_1\right)<0\). Thus, the optimal prices are p1=0 and p2 = l−1(0).

When e = 0, hD(p1, p2) > 0and the payer will not set prices to e = 0; when e = L, from hD(p1, p2) = 0, we have\({p}_2\left[\left(1-L\right)\left(\frac{1}{2}\left(1-r\right)\left(1+L\right)+r\right)+L\right]-\frac{\left(1-t\right){kL}^2}{2}=0\), so that \({p}_2=\frac{\left(1-t\right){kL}^2}{1+r+L\left(1-r\right)\left(2-L\right)}\). p1can be any feasible value.

1.9 Proof for case 2 (Proposition 2)

The drugmaker’s problem is:

$$\underset{p_1,{p}_2}{\max }{h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2\right)$$

s.t. hP≥ 0, hD≥ 0, and p1, p2 ≥ 0.

First, we prove that VP = 0 is always satisfied. Otherwise, if VP > 0, we should be able to find higher prices while keeping the program effect eP unchanged and increasing the value of VD. Thus, VP = 0. When e = 0or e = L, VS = VD + VP is a constant and any prices making VP = 0 are the same to the drugmaker.

Now we replace p1 = g(p2) and e = eP into the drugmaker’s objective function and denote it as G(p2). Thus,

$${G}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)=\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)+\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\left(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)\right).$$

g (p2)is obtained from:

$$\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\left(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)\right)=0.$$

Since \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial e}\)=0, \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}=-\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_1},\mathrm{and}\ \frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}=-\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial {p}_2}\), \({G}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)=\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\left(\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_2}+\frac{\partial {e}^P}{\partial {p}_1}{g}^{\prime}\left({p}_2\right)\right)\).

G (p2) = 0when \(\frac{\partial {V}_D}{\partial e}\)=0 as g(p2)<0. Thus, the optimal p2 should satisfy \({e}^P=\frac{b\left(1-r\right)}{b\left(1-r\right)+k}\)=eS.

Since eS>0, e=0 will not be optimal. If eSL, the optimal decisions are solutions to eP = eS, and VP = 0. The optimal solution is unique because the prices satisfying VP = 0 change in the oppositie directions and the prices satisfying eP = eS change in the same direction. In this case, \(\frac{dp_1^{2\ast }}{dt}=-{\left(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_1}+\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial {p}_2}\frac{dp_2}{dp_1}\right)}^{-1}\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial t}>0\) because \(\frac{\partial {V}_P}{\partial t}<0\) and \(\frac{dp_2}{dp_1}>0\).

If eS>L, then e = L and VP = 0. Thus, \({V}_P=\left(b-{p}_2\right)\left[\left(1-L\right)\left(\frac{1}{2}\left(1-r\right)\left(1+L\right)+r\right)+L\right]-\frac{tkL^2}{2}=0\) so that \({p}_2=b-\frac{tkL^2}{1+r+L\left(1-r\right)\left(2-L\right)}\). p1 can be any non-negative value.

1.10 Proof for case 3 (Proposition 3): p 1 is set by the drugmaker and p 2 by the payer

Since hP(p1, p2) decreases with p2, the payer will reduce p2 as much as possible and p2=0 if the drugmaker’s participation constraint is met. When eSL, hD(p1, p2) is first concave in p1 and then becomes a constant. Thus, the drugmaker’s best response is to choose the local optimum \({p}_1^D\left({p}_2\right)\). If the drugmaker’s local maximum \({h}_D\left({p}_1^D(0),0\right)\ge 0\), then l(0) ≥ 0 and the payer sets p2 = 0. Otherwise, the payer has to increase p2until the maximum of hD(p1, p2) reaches 0. The corresponding hP(p1, p2) ≥ 0because g(p2) ≥ l(p2). The optimal effect is higher than eS.

When eS>L, \({p}_1^D\left({p}_2\right)>{e}^S\). hD(p1, p2) reaches its maximum at e = L, where it is negative if t < 1. Thus, when t < 1, the payer has to set p2above 0 until hD(p1, p2) =0 at e = L, i.e., \({p}_2=\frac{\left(1-t\right){kL}^2}{1+r+L\left(1-r\right)\left(2-L\right)}\). The optimal p1 can be any value between l(p2) and g(p2).

1.11 Proof for case 4 (Proposition 4)

1.11.1 Proof for a)

(1). The prices are decided simultaneously.

When \({p}_1>\hat{p_1}\), hD(p1, p2) is first concave in and then increases with p2. When p2 is increased untile = 0, hD(p1, p2)>0 regardless how low p1 is. The maximum value \({h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2^D\right)\) is larger than the value when eP is reduced to 0. Thus, \({h}_D\left({p}_1,{p}_2^D\right)\)>0 and the payer can reduce p1 to 0. The drugmaker thus set p2 at either g−1(0)or \({p}_2^D(0)\) depending on which one brings a higher hD(p1, p2) while satisfying hP(p1, p2) ≥ 0. When \({g}^{-1}(0)<{p}_2^D(0)\), p2 = g−1(0), and the corresponding program effect may be higher or lower than eS. When \({p}_1\le \hat{p_1}\), hD(p1, p2) increases with p2 so that the drugmaker always prefers the highest feasible p2and the payer sets p1 to 0.

(2). The drugmaker is the first-mover.

The payer will always sets p1= 0. The drugmaker’s decision is the same as in (1).

1.11.2 Proof for b)

When \({p}_1>\hat{p_1}\), the drugmaker chooses \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\) if \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)<{g}^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)<{p}_2^0\left({p}_1\right)\), where VP>0; he chooses g−1(p1)otherwise, where VP=0. When \({p}_1\le \hat{p_1}\), hD(p1, p2) increases with p2 and the drugmaker chooses g−1(p1). The payer, as the first-mover, prefers p1that brings a higher VP. Thus, she tries to induce the drugmaker to choose \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\) instead of g−1(p1) by setting the lowest p1 satisfying \({p}_1>\hat{p_1}\). If \(\hat{p_1}\ge \overline{p_1}\), \({p}_1>\hat{p_1}\) leads to \({g}^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)<{p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\) so that the payer cannot find a p1 to induce the drugmaker choosing \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\). The drugmaker must choose g−1(p1) and the payer thus improves her utility by setting p1 to 0. If \(\hat{p_1}<\overline{p_1}\), the payer can set p1 to the lowest value satisfying both\({p}_1>\hat{p_1}\)and \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)<{g}^{-1}\left({p}_1\right)<{p}_2^0\left({p}_1\right)\) (i.e., \(\underline {p_1}<\hat{p_1}<\overline{p_1}\)) so that the drugmaker chooses \({p}_2^D\left({p}_1\right)\). In this case, the resulting program effect is less than eS.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, H., Huang, T. & Yan, T. A quantitative analysis of risk-sharing agreements with patient support programs for improving medication adherence. Health Care Manag Sci 25, 253–274 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10729-021-09587-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10729-021-09587-9

Keywords

Navigation