Skip to main content
Log in

Bank Competition, Risk, and Subordinated Debt

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies a dynamic model of banking in which banks compete for insured deposits, issue subordinated debt, and invest in either a prudent or a gambling asset. The model allows banks to choose their level of risk after the interest rate on subordinated debt is contracted. We show that requiring banks to issue a small amount of subordinated debt can reduce their gambling incentives. Moreover, when equity capital is more expensive than subordinated debt, adding a subordinated debt requirement to a policy regime that only uses equity capital requirements is Pareto improving.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The other two pillars are minimum capital requirements and supervisory review process. For an excellent exposition on various aspects of market discipline, see Flannery (2001).

  2. For a careful review of these proposals, see Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2003) or Board and Treasury (2000).

  3. See Keeley (1990) for empirical evidence that banks with lower franchise values take higher risk.

  4. Equity capital mainly plays two roles in banks. First, it provides an incentive for banks to invest prudently. Second, it acts as a buffer to cover unexpected losses. As in Hellmann et al. (2000) and Repullo (2004), our paper focuses on the incentive role of equity capital.

  5. There exists extensive evidence supporting this assumption. See the recent survey by Berger et al. (2004). Sources of frictions include entry barriers, switching costs, and product differences etc.

  6. Spatial models have often been used in analyzing banks’ competition in the deposit market. See, for example, Chiappori et al. (1995), and Cordella and Yeyati (2002).

  7. In practice, the products of banks differ along a number of dimensions such as menus of accounts, the number of ATMs, and overdraft facilities. In spatial models location provides a convenient metaphor for product differences in all dimensions.

  8. Following Hellmann et al. (2000), we assume that if a prudent equilibrium exists, then that is the equilibrium that will be selected by banks. Repullo (2004) shows that for markets with intermediate degree of competition, either a prudent equilibrium or a gambling equilibrium can exist, but banks earn strictly higher returns in a prudent equilibrium.

  9. If a bank is solvent even when it obtains the low return, the regulator’s problem would be trivial: all banks will invest in the prudent asset and hence there is no need for regulation. This is because the gambling asset is dominated in terms of expected return by the prudent asset.

  10. There are several reasons to explain why bank equity capital is costly. See Berger et al. (1995) for an excellent discussion. As forcibly argued by Hellmann et al. (2000), if bank capital truly has no opportunity cost, moral hazard would not be an important question in banking.

  11. See Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), Chapter 13.

  12. See Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), Chapter 4.

  13. Following Repullo (2004), we adopt the convention that when the bank is indifferent between a prudent strategy and a gambling strategy, it chooses the prudent one.

  14. Examples of switching costs in the deposit market include the time needed to open a new account, to close the old account, and to learn the new procedures and office locations. Shy (2002) finds that switching costs account for between 0 to 11% of the average balance of a depositor maintained with the bank. Kiser (2002) reports that 32% of the respondents in a survey have never changed banks.

  15. See Sharpe (1997) for a model in which banks are endowed with old depositors and compete only for new ones.

  16. This is because s  ∗  is increasing in h and \(\partial h/\partial \rho <0\).

  17. Figure 2 is drawn using the following parameter values: α = 0.1, β = − 1, γ = π = ρ = 0.2, λ = 0.15, and μ/n = 0.07.

  18. Because subordinated debt issues have finite maturities while equity issues do not, the calculation assumed that each bond issue would be rolled over at its maturity with a new bond of the same maturity, yield, and issuance cost, in perpetuity.

References

  • Acharya VV (2003) Is the international convergence of capital adequacy regulation desirable? J Finance 58:2745–2781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya S, Dreyfus J-F (1989) Optimal bank reorganization policies and the pricing of federal deposit insurance. J Finance 44:1313–1333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2003) Markets for bank subordinated debt and equity in Basel Committee member countries. Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006) International convergence of capital measurement and capital standards (a revised framework; comprehensive version). Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger A, Demirguc-Kunt A, Levine R, Haubrich JG (2004) Bank concentration and competition: an evolution in the making. J Money Credit Bank 36:433–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger A, Herring RJ, Szegö GP (1995) The role of capital in financial institutions. J Bank Financ 19:393–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya S, Planck M, Strobl G, Zechner J (2002) Bank capital regulation with random audits. J Econ Dyn Control 26:1301–1321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blum J (2002) Subordinated debt, market discipline, and banks’ risk taking. J Bank Financ 26:1427–1441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Department of the Treasury (2000) The feasibility and desirability of mandatory subordinated debt. Report submitted to the US Congress

  • Boot A, Schmeits A (2000) Market discipline and incentive problems in conglomerate firms with applications to banking. J Financ Intermed 9:240–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Perez-Castrillo D, Verdier T (1995) Spatial competition in the banking system: localization, cross subsidies and the regulation of deposit rates. Eur Econ Rev 39:889–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordella T, Yeyati EL (2002) Financial opening, deposit insurance, and risk in a model of banking competition. Eur Econ Rev 46:471–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Covitz DM, Hancock D, Kwast ML (2004) A reconsideration of the risk sensitivity of U.S. banking organization subordinated debt spreads: a sample selection approach. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 73–92 September

  • Dangl T, Lehar A (2004) Value-at-risk vs. building block regulation in banking. J Financ Intermed 13:96–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Decamps J-P, Rochet J-C, Roger B (2004) The three pillars of Basel II: optimizing the mix. J Financ Intermed 13:132–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery M (1982) Retail bank deposits as quasi-fixed factors of production. Am Econ Rev 72:527–536

    Google Scholar 

  • Flannery M (2001) The faces of market discipline. J Financ Serv Res 20:107–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fries S, Mella-Barral P, Perraudin W (1997) Optimal bank reorganization and the fair pricing of deposit guarantees. J Bank Finan 21:441–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellmann TF, Murdock KC, Stiglitz, JE (2000) Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: are capital requirements enough? Am Econ Rev 90:147–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Am Econ Rev 76:323–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeley M (1990) Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking. Am Econ Rev 80:1183–1200

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiser E (2002) Predicting household switching behavior and switching costs at depository institutions. Review of Industrial Organization 20:349–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1978) On the cost of deposit insurance when there are surveillance costs. J Bus 51:439–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Repullo R (2004) Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking. J Financ Intermed 13:156–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet J-C (2004) Rebalancing the three pillars of Basel II. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 7–21 September

  • Salop S (1979) Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J Econ 10:141–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos JAC (2004) Do markets discipline all banks equally? Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, USA

  • Sharpe SA (1997) The effect of consumer switching costs on prices: a theory and its application to the bank deposit market. Review of Industrial Organization 12:79–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shy O (2002) A quick-and-easy method for estimating switching costs. Int J Ind Organ 20:71–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Erwan Morellec and Elu von Thadden for constant support and advice. I would like to thank Michel Habib, Enrique Schroth, Lucy White, Yu Zhang, and especially an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions, and the University of Rochester for its hospitality. Financial support from the NCCR FinRisk and the Swiss National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jijun Niu.

Appendix

Appendix

Lemma 1

The first no-gambling condition (9) is equivalent to

$$\left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left[ {\gamma - \alpha - 2\left( {h - 1} \right)\frac{\mu }{n}} \right] - \left[ {\pi \left( {1 + \rho } \right) - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)} \right]k - \left[ {\pi \left( {1 + \lambda } \right) - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)} \right]s \leqslant 0,$$
(18)

where h is given by Eq. 12.

Proof

Differentiating the left-hand side of Eq. 9 with respect to k j , and using assumption (1) and (2), yields

$$ \left( -1+\frac{1-\pi }{1+\rho }\left( 1+\gamma \right) \right) D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) <\left( -1+\frac{1+\alpha }{1+\rho }\right) D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) <0. $$

Hence the shareholders choose k j  = k.

Similarly, differentiating the left-hand side of Eq. 9 with respect to s j , and using assumption (1) and (3), yields

$$ \frac{1-\pi }{1+\rho }\left( 1+\gamma -\frac{1+\lambda }{1-\pi }\right) D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) <\frac{1-\pi }{1+\rho }\left( 1+\gamma -\frac{ 1+\alpha }{1-\pi }\right) D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) <0. $$

Hence the shareholders choose s j  = s.

Finally, substituting k j  = k and s j  = s into Eq. 9, and then differentiating the left-hand side of it with respect to r j , yields the following first-order condition:

$$ r_{j}=\frac{r_{P}+r_{G}}{2}, $$

where

$$ r_{G}=\gamma -\frac{\mu }{n}-\left( \frac{1+\rho }{1-\pi }-1-\gamma \right) k-\left( \frac{1+\lambda }{1-\pi }-1-\gamma \right) s. \label{r_G} $$
(19)

Therefore

$$ D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) =\frac{1}{n}+\frac{r_{G}-r_{P}}{2\mu }. $$

Substituting r j and \(D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) \) back into Eq. 9 and simplifying terms yields

$$ \left( \frac{\mu }{n}+\frac{r_{G}-r_{P}}{2}\right) ^{2}\leq h^{2}\left( \frac{\mu }{n}\right) ^{2}. $$

When \(D\left( r_{j},r_{P}\right) \geq 0\), above inequality is equivalent to

$$ r_{G}-r_{P}\leq 2\left( h-1\right) \frac{\mu }{n}. $$

Substituting r G from Eq. 19 and r P from Eq. 7 into this expression and simplifying terms yields the desired result. □

Lemma 2

The second no-gambling condition Eq. 10 is equivalent to

$$ \left( 1-\pi \right) \left[ \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \left( 1+s\right) -\left( h^{2}-1\right) \frac{\mu }{n}\right] -\left[ \pi \left( 1+\rho \right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \right] k\leq 0. \label{no_gambling_2} $$
(20)

Proof

Substitute \(D\left( r_{P},r_{P}\right) =1/n\) and V P from Eqs. 8 into (10). Simple calculations yield the desired result. □

Proof of Proposition 1

Substituting s = 0 and k = 0 into Eq. 18, and rearranging terms, the first no-gambling condition becomes

$$ \frac{\mu }{n}\geq \frac{\gamma -\alpha }{2\left( h-1\right) }. \label{c_1} $$
(21)

Similarly, substituting s = 0 and k = 0 into Eq. 20, and rearranging terms, the second no-gambling condition becomes

$$ \frac{\mu }{n}\geq \frac{\gamma -\alpha }{h^{2}-1}. \label{c_2} $$
(22)

Because h > 1, condition (22) is satisfied as long as Eq. 21 is satisfied. Therefore, no prudent equilibrium can exist if

$$ \frac{\mu }{n}<\frac{\gamma -\alpha }{2\left( h-1\right) }. $$

Proof of Proposition 2

Substituting k = 0 into Eq. 18, the first no-gambling condition becomes

$$ \left( 1-\pi \right) \left[ \gamma -\alpha -2\left( h-1\right) \frac{\mu }{n} \right] -\left[ \pi \left( 1+\lambda \right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \right] s\leq 0. \label{s_c_1} $$
(23)

It then follows from Eq. 14 that Eq. 23 can be rewritten as

$$ s\geq \frac{\left( 1-\pi \right) \left[ \gamma -\alpha -2\left( h-1\right) \frac{\mu }{n}\right] }{\pi \left( 1+\lambda \right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) }. \label{s_bigger} $$
(24)

Substituting k = 0 into Eq. 20, and rearranging terms, the second no-gambling condition becomes

$$ s\leq \left( \frac{h^{2}-1}{\gamma -\alpha }\right) \frac{\mu }{n}-1. \label{s_smaller} $$
(25)

The bank will have no incentive to deviate when both conditions (24) and (25) are satisfied. For this to be possible, we need

$$ \frac{\left( 1-\pi \right) \left[ \gamma -\alpha -2\left( h-1\right) \frac{ \mu }{n}\right] }{\pi \left( 1+\lambda \right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) }\leq \left( \frac{h^{2}-1}{\gamma -\alpha }\right) \frac{\mu }{n}-1, $$

or

$$ {\kern65pt} \frac{\mu }{n}\geq \frac{\pi \left( 1+\lambda \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) }{\pi \left( 1+\lambda \right) \left( h^{2}-1\right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \left( h-1\right) ^{2}}. $$

Proof of Proposition 3

Assumption (1) and (2) imply that

$$ \pi \left( 1+\rho \right) -\left( 1-\pi \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) =\left( \rho -\alpha \right) \pi +\alpha -\left( 1-\pi \right) \gamma +\pi >0. \label{before_k_positive} $$
(26)

Therefore the first no-gambling condition, Eq. 18, can be rewritten as k ≥ k 1, where the parameter k 1 is given by Eq. 15. Similarly, the second no-gambling condition, Eq. 20, can be rewritten as k ≥ k 2, where k 2 is given by Eq. 16.

To satisfy both conditions, the regulator sets \(k\geq \max \left( k_{1},k_{2}\right) \). □

Proof of Proposition 4

Some calculations show that k 1 = k 2 when s = s  ∗ , where s  ∗  is given by Eq. 17. Because h > 1, we have s  ∗  > 0.

Expression (14) implies that k 1 is a linearly decreasing function of s, while assumption (1) implies that k 2 is a linearly increasing function of s. Therefore, for s < s  ∗ , we have k = k 1, or dk/ds < 0. Similarly, for s ≥ s  ∗ , we have k = k 2, or dk/ds > 0. □

Proof of Proposition 5

From the proof of Proposition 4, we know that for s < s  ∗ , we have\(\ k=k_{1}\), thus

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{dr_P }}{{d_S }}}{ = \frac{{\partial r_P }}{{\partial _S }} + \frac{{\partial r_P }}{{\partial k}}\frac{{dk}}{{ds}}} \\ {}{ = - \left( {\lambda - \alpha } \right) + \left( {\rho - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\pi \left( {1 + \lambda } \right) - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)}}{{\pi \left( {1 + \rho } \right) - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)}}} \\ {}{ = \frac{{\left( {\rho - \lambda } \right)\left[ {\alpha - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\gamma + \pi } \right]}}{{\alpha + \left( {\rho - \alpha } \right)\pi - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\gamma + \pi }}.} \\ \end{array} $$

It follows from assumption (1) and (2) that for s < s  ∗ , we have dr P /ds > 0 if and only if ρ > λ . This implies that when equity capital is more expensive than subordinated debt (i.e., when ρ > λ) and for s < s  ∗ , an increase of s will increase the returns of the depositors. At the same time, the bank’s expected returns do not change, and the regulator (as the deposit insurance provider) does not incur any insurance outflow. Hence the policy is Pareto improving. □

Proof

that k 1 is decreasing in π

Rewrite Eq. 12 as \(\pi =\rho \left( h^{2}-1\right) /\left( \rho h^{2}+1\right) \). Substituting it into Eq. 15 and simplifying terms yields

$$ k_{1}=\frac{\left( 1+\rho \right) \left[ \gamma -\alpha -2(h-1)\frac{\mu }{n} \right] -\left[ \rho \left( h^{2}-1\right) \left( 1+\lambda \right) -\left( 1+\rho \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \right] s}{\rho \left( h^{2}-1\right) \left( 1+\rho \right) -\left( 1+\rho \right) \left( \gamma -\alpha \right) }. $$

It is easy to verify that \(\partial k_{1}/\partial h<0\). But \(\partial h/\partial \pi >0\), therefore \(\partial k_{1}/\partial \pi <0\). □

Proof

that k 2 is decreasing in π

Substituting Eq. 12 into Eq. 16 and simplifying terms yields

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {k_2 = }{\frac{{\left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 + s} \right) - \pi \left( {1 + {1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \rho }} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} \rho }} \right)\tfrac{\mu }{n}}}{{\pi \left( {1 + \rho } \right) - \left( {1 - \pi } \right)\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)}}} \\ = {\frac{{\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 + s} \right) - \pi \left[ {\left( {\gamma - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 + s} \right) + \left( {1 + {1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \rho }} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} \rho }} \right)\tfrac{\mu }{n}} \right]}}{{\pi \left( {1 + \rho + \gamma - \alpha } \right) - \gamma + \alpha }}.} \\ \end{array} $$

Because \(\left( \gamma -\alpha \right) \left( 1+s\right) +\left( 1+1/\rho \right) \frac{\mu }{n}>0\), and 1 + ρ + γ − α > 0, we have \( \partial k_{2}/\partial \pi <0\). □

Proof

that s  ∗  is decreasing in π

Rewrite Eq. 12 as \(\pi =\rho \left( h^{2}-1\right) /\left( \rho h^{2}+1\right) \). Substituting it into Eq. 17 and simplifying terms yields

$$ s^{\ast }=\frac{\left( 1+\rho \right) \mu }{\rho \left( 1+\lambda \right) n} \left( \frac{h-1}{h+1}\right) . $$

It is easy to verify that \(\partial s^{\ast }/\partial h>0\). But \(\partial h/\partial \pi >0\), therefore \(\partial s^{\ast }/\partial \pi >0\). □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Niu, J. Bank Competition, Risk, and Subordinated Debt. J Finan Serv Res 33, 37–56 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-007-0022-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-007-0022-3

Keywords

Navigation