Skip to main content
Log in

Superquantile/CVaR risk measures: second-order theory

  • S.I.: Risk Management Approaches in Engineering Applications
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Superquantiles, which refer to conditional value-at-risk in the same way that quantiles refer to value-at-risk, have many advantages in the modeling of risk in finance and engineering. However, some applications may benefit from a further step, from superquantiles to second-order superquantiles. Measures of risk based on second-order superquantiles have recently been explored in some settings, but key parts of the theory have been lacking: descriptions of the associated risk envelopes and risk identifiers. Those missing ingredients are supplied in this paper, and moreover not just for second-order superquantiles, but also for a much broader class of mixed superquantile measures of risk. Such dualizing expressions facilitate the development of dual methods for mixed and second-order superquantile risk minimization as well as superquantile regression, a proposed second-order version of quantile regression.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. They preferred “average” because “conditional” could have differing usages. This issue also adds motivation to our passage to “superquantiles.”

  2. The term “risk envelope” was introduced in Rockafellar et al. (2002).

  3. This term was introduced in Rockafellar et al. (2006), although the sets in question were handled earlier as being the subdifferentials of convex analysis for the risk measure functionals in question.

  4. For a set S with a topology, let \(\mathcal{{B}}_S\) be its Borel sigma-algebra.

  5. Here, and throughout the paper, m denotes Lebesgue measure.

  6. We note that \(\mathcal{{Q}}\) resembles the Aumann integral (see for example Castaing and Valadier 1977) of the set-valued mapping \(\beta \mapsto \mathcal{{Q}}_\beta \).

  7. Here continuity is with respect to the product topology of the norm-topologies on [0, 1) and \(\mathcal{{L}}^2\).

  8. With \(\mathcal{{L}}^2\) consisting of equivalence classes of functions identical up to on a set of \(\mathbb {P}\)-measure zero, uniqueness of course is in the sense of such equivalence classes.

  9. Again, uniqueness is up to on a set of \(\mathbb {P}\)-measure zero.

  10. Recall that \(f:\mathbb {R}^n\rightarrow \overline{\mathbb {R}}\) is strictly differentiable at a point \(\bar{x}\) if \(f(\bar{x})\) is finite and there is a vector \(v\in \mathbb {R}^n\) such that \((f(x^{\prime }) - f(x) - \langle v, x^{\prime } - x\rangle ){/}|x^{\prime }-x| \rightarrow 0\) whenever \(x,x^{\prime }\rightarrow \bar{x}\) and \(x^{\prime }\ne x\); see Rockafellar and Wets (1998, Definition 9.17).

  11. A subset of a set of Lebesgue measure zero is negligible.

  12. We refer to Rockafellar and Uryasev (2013) for a general treatment of measures of error and regret.

References

  • Acerbi, C. (2002). Spectral measures of risk: A coherent representation of subjective risk aversion. Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 1505–1518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M., & Heath, D. (1999). Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance, 9(3), 203–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castaing, C., & Valadier, M. (1977). Convex analysis and measurable multifunctions. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cheridito, P., & Li, T. (2008). Dual characterization of properties of risk measures on orlicz hearts. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 2(1), 29–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chun, S. Y., Shapiro, A., & Uryasev, S. (2012). Conditional value-at-risk and average value-at-risk: Estimation and asymptotics. Operations Research, 60(4), 739–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datko, R. (1973). On the integration of set-valued mappings in a Banach space. Fundamenta Mathematicae, 78, 205–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Föllmer, H., & Schied, A. (2002). Stochastic finance (1st ed.). de Gruyter. Berlin, New York: Springer.

  • Föllmer, H., & Schied, A. (2011). Stochastic finance: An introduction in discrete time (3rd ed.). de Gruyter. Berlin, New York: Springer.

  • Jouini, E., Schachermayer, W., & Touzi, N. (2006). Law invariant risk measures have the Fatou property. In S. Kusuoka & T. Maruyama (Eds.), Advances in mathematical economics (Vol. 9, pp. 49–71). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kusuoka, S. (2001). On law-invariant coherent risk measures. In S. Kusuoka & T. Maruyama (Eds.), Advances in mathematical economics (Vol. 3, pp. 83–95). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mausser, H., & Rosen, D. (1998). Efficient risk/return frontiers for credit risk. Algo Research Quarterly, 2(4), 35–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N., & Ruszczynski, A. (2011). Risk-averse two-stage stochastic linear programming: Modeling and decomposition. Operations Research, 59(1), 125–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miranda, S. (2014). Superquantile regression: Theory, algorithms, and applications. Ph.D. thesis, Naval Postgraduate School, Monterey, CA, USA.

  • Noyan, N., & Rudolf, G. (2015). Kusuoka representations of coherent risk measures in general probability spaces. Annals of Operations Research, 229, 591–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pflug, G. C. (2006). On distortion functionals. Statistics and Decisions, 24, 45–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pflug, G. C., & Römisch, W. (2007). Modeling, measuring and managing risk. Singapore: World Scientific.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T. (1971). Convex integral functionals and duality. In E. Zaratonello (Ed.), Contributions to nonlinear functional analysis (pp. 215–236). New York: Academic Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Royset, J. O. (2010). On buffered failure probability in design and optimization of structures. Reliability Engineering & System Safety, 95, 499–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Royset, J. O. (2013). Superquantiles and their applications to risk, random variables, and regression. In H. Topaloglu (Ed.), Tutorials in operations research (pp.151–167). INFORMS.

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Royset, J. O. (2014). Random variables, monotone relations and convex analysis. Mathematical Programming B, 148, 297–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Royset, J. O. (2015). Measures of residual risk with connections to regression, risk tracking, surrogate models, and ambiguity. SIAM Journal on Optimization, 25(2), 1179–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., Royset, J. O., & Miranda, S. I. (2014). Superquantile regression with applications to buffered reliability, uncertainty quantification, and conditional value-at-risk. European Journal of Operational Research, 234(1), 140–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Uryasev, S. (2000). Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. Journal of Risk, 2, 21–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Uryasev, S. (2002). Conditional value-at-risk for general loss distributions. Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 1443–1471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Uryasev, S. (2013). The fundamental risk quadrangle in risk management, optimization and statistical estimation. Surveys in Operations Research and Management Science, 18, 33–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., Uryasev, S., & Zabarankin, M. (2002). Deviation measures in risk analysis and optimization. Technical report, Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering, University of Florida.

  • Rockafellar, R. T., Uryasev, S., & Zabarankin, M. (2006). Generalized deviations in risk analysis. Finance and Stochastics, 10, 51–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar, R. T., & Wets, R. (1998). Variational analysis (Vol. 317, 3rd printing-2009 ed.). Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaft. Berlin: Springer.

  • Ruszczynski, A. (2013). Advances in risk-averse optimization. In H. Topaloglu (Ed.), Tutorials in operations research (pp. 168–190). INFORMS. Catonsville, MD.

  • Ruszczynski, A., & Shapiro, A. (2006). Optimization of convex risk functions. Mathematics of Operations Research, 31, 433–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, A. (2013). On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures. Mathematics of Operations Research, 38(1), 142–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, A., Dentcheva, D., & Ruszczynski, A. (2009). Lectures on stochastic programming: Modeling and theory. SIAM. Philadelphia, PA.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johannes O. Royset.

Additional information

This material is based upon work supported in part by the U. S. Air Force Office of Scientific Research under Grants FA9550-11-1-0206 and F1ATAO1194GOO1 and DARPA under Grant HR0011517798.

Appendix

Appendix

As support for proving Proposition 2.3 in Sect. 2, we need the following consequence of the Fubini–Tonelli’s Theorem.

Proposition 4.3

Suppose that \((\mathcal{{X}}, \mathcal{{A}}, \mu )\) and \((\mathcal{{Y}},\mathcal{{B}},\nu )\) are sigma-finite measure spaces. If \(f:\mathcal{{X}}\times \mathcal{{Y}}\rightarrow \overline{\mathbb {R}}\) is measurable with respect to the product sigma-algebra on \(\mathcal{{X}}\times \mathcal{{Y}}\) and \(g:\mathcal{{X}}\times \mathcal{{Y}}\rightarrow \overline{\mathbb {R}}\) is integrable with respect to the product measure \(\mu \times \nu \), with \(f(x,y)\ge g(x,y)\) for \((\mu \times \nu )\)-a.e. \((x,y)\in \mathcal{{X}}\times \mathcal{{Y}}\), then the following hold:

  1. (i)

    the function \(h_1 = \int f(x,\cdot ) d\mu (x)\) is \(\mathcal{{B}}\)-measurable,

  2. (ii)

    the function \(h_2 = \int f(\cdot ,y) d\nu (y)\) is \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable,

  3. (iii)

    and

    $$\begin{aligned} \int f d(\mu \times \nu ) = \int \left[ \int f(x,y) d\mu (x)\right] d\nu (y) = \int \left[ \int f(x,y) d\nu (y)\right] d\mu (x). \end{aligned}$$

Proof

We recall that the integral of the sum of a nonnegative measurable function and an integrable function equates the sum of the individual integrals under the usual rules for handling addition with infinity. Then,

$$\begin{aligned} h_1 = \int f(x,\cdot ) d\mu (x) = \int (f-g)(x,\cdot ) d\mu (x) + \int g(x,\cdot ) d\mu (x) \end{aligned}$$

is \(\mathcal{{B}}\)-measurable since both terms on the right-hand side are \(\mathcal{{B}}\)-measurable by the Fubini–Tonelli Theorem. A similar argument yields the conclusion for \(h_2\). The final assertion follows by applying the Fubini–Tonelli Theorem to \(f-g\) and g, and the above rule about interchange of summation and integration. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2.3

For every \(X\in \mathcal{{L}}^2\), \(\bar{q}_X\) is continuous and finite on [0, 1) and therefore \(\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\)-measurable. Moreover, \(\bar{q}_X \ge E[X]\) and therefore \(\mathcal{{R}}(X) \ge E[X] > -\infty \). Consequently, \(\mathcal{{R}}\) is well-defined with values in \([E[X], \infty ]\). Its regularity and positive homogeneity follow directly from those of \(\mathcal{{R}}_\alpha \); see Rockafellar and Uryasev (2013). Since \(\bar{q}_X\) is strictly increasing on [0, 1) for nonconstant X, we have that if \(\lambda (\{0\})<1\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{{R}}(X) = E[X]\lambda (\{0\}) + \int _{1>\beta >0} \bar{q}_X(\beta )~d\lambda (\beta ) > E[X]\lambda (\{0\}) + E[X](1-\lambda (\{0\}) = E[X] \end{aligned}$$

and the strict lower bound follows. From (6),

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{{R}}(X) \le \int _{0}^1 E[X] + \frac{\sigma (X)}{\sqrt{1-\beta }} d\lambda (\beta ) = E[X] + \sigma (X)\int _{0}^1 \frac{1}{\sqrt{1-\beta }} d\lambda (\beta )<\infty \end{aligned}$$

under the stated assumption, which establishes the corresponding finiteness on \(\mathcal{{L}}^2\). In the case of \(\sup X <\infty \), finiteness of \(\mathcal{{R}}(X)\) follows trivially.

We next consider the alternative expression. By definition,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{{R}}(X) = \int _0^1 \left[ \int _0^1 q_X(\beta ) \psi (\alpha ,\beta ) d\beta \right] d\lambda (\alpha ), \end{aligned}$$
(20)

with \(\psi (\alpha ,\beta ) = \frac{1}{1-\alpha }\) if \(0\le \alpha < \beta < 1\) and \(\psi (\alpha ,\beta ) = 0\) otherwise. We equip \([0,1)\times (0,1)\) with the product measure \(\lambda \times m\) defined on the product sigma-algebra \(\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\otimes \mathcal{{B}}_{(0,1)}\). It is obvious that \(\psi :[0,1)\times (0,1)\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) is \((\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\otimes \mathcal{{B}}_{(0,1)})\)-measurable and likewise \(q_X\), viewed as a function on \([0,1)\times (0,1)\) that is constant in its first argument, due its monotonicity. Consequently, the function \((\alpha ,\beta )\mapsto q_X(\beta ) \psi (\alpha ,\beta )\) is measurable in the same sense. Then, we look toward the interchange of integration order in (20).

We consider three cases. (i) Suppose that \(X\ge 0\) a.e. Then, \(q_X\ge 0\) and \(q_X\psi \ge 0\), and the interchange of integration order is permitted by Tonelli–Fubini’s Theorem. (ii) Suppose that \(X\le 0\) a.e. Then, \(-q_X\ge 0\) and \(-q_X\psi \ge 0\), and the interchange of integration order is again permitted by Tonelli-Fubini’s Theorem. (iii) Suppose that neither (i) nor (ii) holds. Then, there exists a \(\beta _X \in (0,1)\) such that \(q_X(\beta ) \ge 0\) for \(\beta \ge \beta _X\) and \(q_X(\beta ) \le 0\) for \(\beta \le \beta _X\). In view of Proposition 4.3, it suffices to find an integrable, lower-bounding function of \(q_X\psi \). Let \(g:[0,1)\times (0,1) \rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) be given by

$$\begin{aligned} g(\alpha ,\beta ) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} q_X(\beta ){/}(1-\beta _X) &{}\quad \text{ if }\; 0\le \alpha < \beta \le \beta _X\\ q_X(\beta ) &{}\quad \text{ if }\; 0\le \alpha < \beta <1, \beta _X<\beta \\ 0 &{}\quad \text{ otherwise. }\end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, \(q_X\psi \ge g\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \int |g| d(\lambda \times m) \le \frac{1}{1-\beta _X}\int |q_X| d(\lambda \times m) = \frac{1}{1-\beta _X} \int _0^1 \left[ \int _0^1 |q_X(\beta )| d\beta \right] d\lambda (\alpha ), \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where the equality follows by Tonelli–Fubini’s Theorem. The inner integral simplifies to

$$\begin{aligned} \int _0^1 |q_X(\beta )| d\beta = \int _{\beta _X}^1 q_X(\beta ) d\beta - \int _0^{\beta _X} q_X(\beta ) d\beta = (1-\beta _X)\bar{q}_X(\beta _X) - \int _0^{\beta _X} q_X(\beta ) d\beta . \end{aligned}$$

The last term requires further simplification. Recall that for \(\alpha \in (0,1)\),

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{\alpha }\int _0^\alpha q_X(\beta )d\beta = -\frac{1}{\alpha }\int _{1-\alpha }^1 q_{-X}(\beta )d\beta = -\bar{q}_{-X}(1-\alpha ). \end{aligned}$$

Applying this result, the inner integral from above simplifies further to

$$\begin{aligned} \int _0^1 |q_X(\beta )| d\beta = (1-\beta _X)\bar{q}_X(\beta _X) + \beta _X\bar{q}_{-X}(1-\beta _X)<\infty . \end{aligned}$$

Consequently in view of (21), g is integrable and therefore furnishes the necessary lower-bounding, integrable function in Proposition 4.3, which completes part (iii). We are therefore permitted to interchange the order of integration in (20) and get

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{{R}}(X)= & {} \int _0^1 \left[ \int _0^1 q_X(\beta ) \psi (\alpha ,\beta ) d\beta \right] d\lambda (\alpha ) = \int _0^1 q_X(\beta ) \left[ \int _0^1 \psi (\alpha ,\beta ) d\lambda (\alpha )\right] d\beta \\= & {} \int _0^1 q_X(\beta ) \varphi (\beta ) d\beta , \end{aligned}$$

where the last equality follows from the definition of \(\varphi \).

The final assertions follow from recognizing that the Lebesgue–Stieltjes measure \(d\varphi \) associated with a function \(\varphi \) has \(d\varphi (\alpha ) = \frac{1}{1-\alpha } d\lambda (\alpha )\) for a weighting measure \(\lambda \) on [0, 1). \(\square \)

Now we articulate other definitions and technical results required in the paper.

Definition 4.4

Let \((T,\mathcal{{A}},\mu )\) be a complete measure space, with \(\mu \) sigma-finite, \(\mathcal{{X}}\) a separable reflexive Banach space, and \(\mathcal{{M}}\) a linear subspace of the linear space of all \((\mathcal{{A}},\mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-measurable functions \(x:T\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\). The set \(\mathcal{{M}}\) is \((\mathcal{{A}},\mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-decomposable if, whenever \(x\in \mathcal{{M}}\) and \(x_0:S\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\) is a bounded \((\mathcal{{A}},\mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-measurable function on a set \(S\in \mathcal{{A}}\), with \(\mu (S)<\infty \), then the function \(y:T\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\) given by

$$\begin{aligned} y(t) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} x_0(t) &{}\quad \text{ if }\; t\in S\\ x(t) &{}\quad \text{ if }\; t \in T{\setminus } S \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

also belongs to \(\mathcal{{M}}\).

Definition 4.5

In the notation of Definition 4.4, we say that a function \(f:T\times \mathcal{{X}}\rightarrow (-\infty , \infty ]\) is a normal integrand if the following hold:

  1. (i)

    f is \((\mathcal{{A}}\otimes \mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-measurable and

  2. (ii)

    for every \(t\in T\), \(f(t, \cdot )\) is lower semicontinuous on \(\mathcal{{X}}\) and not identical to \(\infty \).

Proposition 4.6

Suppose that the conditions and notation of Definition 4.4 hold and \(f:T\times \mathcal{{X}}\rightarrow (-\infty , \infty ]\) is a normal integrand. Then, the following hold:

  1. (i)

    the functions \(t\mapsto \inf _{\xi \in \mathcal{{X}}} f(t,\xi )\) and \(t\mapsto f(t,x(t))\), with \(x:T\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\) \((\mathcal{{A}},\mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-measurable, are \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable and

  2. (ii)

    if \(\mathcal{{M}}\) is \((\mathcal{{A}},\mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-decomposable and there exists an \(x\in \mathcal{{M}}\) such that \(\int f(t,x(t)) ~d\mu (t) <\infty \), then

    $$\begin{aligned} \inf _{x\in \mathcal{{M}}} \int f(t,x(t)) ~d\mu (t) = \int \varphi (t) ~d\mu (t),\quad \text{ where }\quad \varphi (t) = \inf _{\xi \in \mathcal{{X}}} f(t,\xi ). \end{aligned}$$
    (22)

Proof

First, we consider \(t\mapsto \inf _{\xi \in \mathcal{{X}}} f(t,\xi )\). For measurable spaces \((\mathcal{{X}}_1,\mathcal{{A}}_1)\) and \((\mathcal{{X}}_2,\mathcal{{A}}_2)\), we recall that a set-valued mapping \(S:\mathcal{{X}}_1\rightrightarrows \mathcal{{X}}_2\) is \((\mathcal{{A}}_1,\mathcal{{A}}_2)\)-measurable if its graph is measurable in the sense that

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ (x_1,x_2)\in \mathcal{{X}}_1\times \mathcal{{X}}_2|x_2 \in S(x_1)\right\} \in \mathcal{{A}}_1 \otimes \mathcal{{A}}_2, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\mathcal{{A}}_1 \otimes \mathcal{{A}}_2\) is the product sigma-algebra generated by \(\mathcal{{A}}_1\) and \(\mathcal{{A}}_2\). Since f is a normal integrand, the set-valued mapping \(t\mapsto \mathop {\mathrm{epi}}f(t,\cdot )\) is \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable and closed-valued; see for example Rockafellar (1971, Proposition 1). By Rockafellar (1971, Theorem 1(f)), there exists a countable collection \(\{g_i\}_{i\in I}\) of \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable functions \(g_i:T\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\times \mathbb {R}\) of the form \(g_i(t) = (x_i(t),\alpha _i(t))\), \(x_i(t)\in \mathcal{{X}}\) and \(\alpha _i(t)\in \mathbb {R}\), such that

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {\mathrm{epi}}f(t,\cdot ) = \mathop {\mathrm{cl}}\{ g_i(t)\}_{i\in I}\quad \text{ for } \text{ all }\quad t\in T, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\mathop {\mathrm{cl}}\) denotes closure. The mapping \(t\mapsto \alpha _i(t)\) is also \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable. Consequently,

$$\begin{aligned} \inf _{\xi \in \mathcal{{X}}} f(t,\xi ) = \inf _{i\in I} \alpha _i(t)\quad \text{ for } \text{ all }\quad t\in T \end{aligned}$$

and the conclusion follows from the fact that the pointwise infimum of a countable collection of measurable functions is a measurable function.

Second, we consider \(t\mapsto f(t,x(t))\), which is a composition of f with the measurable mapping \(t\mapsto (t,x(t))\) and therefore measurable.

Third, we establish part (ii) by following the arguments in the proof of Theorem 2 in Rockafellar (1971). By assumption there exists a function \(x_1\in \mathcal{{M}}\) and a \(\mu \)-integrable function \(\alpha _1:T\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} f(t,x_1(t)) \le \alpha _1(t)\quad \text{ for } \text{ every }\quad t\in T. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\varphi (t) \le f(t,x(t))\) for every function \(x\in \mathcal{{M}}\) and \(t\in T\) by definition and \(\varphi \) is \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable by part (i), the integral of \(\varphi \) is well-defined and either finite or equals \(-\infty \). Consequently, the inequality \(\ge \) holds in (22). Now, let \(\gamma \in \mathbb {R}\) be such that

$$\begin{aligned} \int \varphi (t) d\mu (t) < \gamma . \end{aligned}$$
(23)

We will prove the existence of a function \(x\in \mathcal{{M}}\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} \int f(t,x(t)) d\mu (t) < \gamma , \end{aligned}$$
(24)

thereby establishing part (ii). From (23) and the properties of \((T,\mathcal{{A}},\mu )\), there exists a \(\mu \)-integrable function \(\alpha _0:T\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) such that \(\varphi (t) < \alpha _0(t)\) for every \(t\in T\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \int \alpha _0(t) ~d\mu (t) < \gamma . \end{aligned}$$
(25)

We define the set-valued mapping \(S:T\rightrightarrows \mathcal{{X}}\) by

$$\begin{aligned} S(t) = \left\{ \xi \in \mathcal{{X}}~|~f(t,\xi ) \le \alpha _0(t)\right\} \quad \text{ for }\quad t\in T. \end{aligned}$$

Since the function \((t,\xi )\mapsto f(t,\xi ) - \alpha _0(t)\) is \((\mathcal{{A}}\otimes \mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{X}}})\)-measurable, S is also \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable. Moreover, S(t) is for each \(t\in T\) closed and nonempty. Since S is \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable, there exists a \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable selection \(x_0\), i.e., a \(\mathcal{{A}}\)-measurable function \(x_0\) such that \(x_0(t) \in S(t)\) for every \(t\in T\); see for example the corollary of Theorem 1 in Rockafellar (1971). Since (25) holds, there exists a measurable set \(T_0\subset T\), with \(\mu (T_0) < \infty \), such that

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{T_0} \alpha _0(t) d\mu (t) + \int _{T{\setminus }T_0} \alpha _1(t) ~d\mu (t) < \gamma . \end{aligned}$$
(26)

By the construction of S in terms of \(\alpha _0\), the measurable selection \(x_0\) can be chosen to be bounded on \(T_0\). Let \(x:T\rightarrow \mathcal{{X}}\) be such that \(x(t) = x_0(t)\) for \(t\in T_0\) and \(x(t) = x_1(t)\) for \(t\in T{\setminus }T_0\). Then, \(x\in \mathcal{{M}}\) by the assumption of decomposability, and we have that \(f(t,x(t)) \le \alpha _0(t)\) for \(t\in T_0\) and \(f(t,x(t)) \le \alpha _1(t)\) for \(t\in T{\setminus } T_0\). From (26) we then conclude (24), which establishes part (ii). \(\square \)

Lemma 4.7

If \(q:[0,1)\rightarrow \mathcal{{L}}^2\) is \((\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}, \mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{L}}^2})\)-measurable, then

  1. (i)

    the function \(f_1:[0,1)\times \Omega \rightarrow \overline{\mathbb {R}}\) given by \(f_1(\beta ,\omega ) = q(\beta )(\omega )\) is \((\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\otimes \mathcal{{F}})\)-measurable, and

  2. (ii)

    the function \(f_2:[0,1)\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) given by \(f_2(\beta ) = \Vert q(\beta )\Vert _2\) is \(\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\)-measurable.

Proof

For part (i) simply observe that \(f_1 = g \circ h\), where \(h:[0,1)\times \Omega \rightarrow \mathcal{{L}}^2 \times \Omega \), with \(h(\alpha ,\omega ) = (q(\alpha ),\omega )\), and \(g:\mathcal{{L}}^2\times \Omega \rightarrow \overline{\mathbb {R}}\), with \(g(Q,\omega ) = Q(\omega )\). The conclusion then follows from the measurability of q and elements of \(\mathcal{{L}}^2\), and the fact that composition of measurable functions is measurable. Next, we consider part (ii). A trivial extension of part (i) establishes that the function \((\beta ,\omega )\mapsto [q(\beta )(\omega )]^2\) is \((\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\otimes \mathcal{{F}})\)-measurable. Since it is also nonnegative, it follows from Tonelli–Fubini’s Theorem that \([f_2(\cdot )]^2\) is \(\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}\)-measurable. \(\square \)

The following is a direct consequence of Definition 4.4.

Proposition 4.8

The set \(\mathcal{{M}}\) is \((\bar{\mathcal{{B}}}_{[0,1)}, \mathcal{{B}}_{\mathcal{{L}}^2})\)-decomposable.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rockafellar, R.T., Royset, J.O. Superquantile/CVaR risk measures: second-order theory. Ann Oper Res 262, 3–28 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2129-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2129-0

Keywords

Navigation