Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Auditing Shaked and Shanthikumar’s ‘excess wealth’

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A notion called “excess wealth” was introduced by Shaked and Shanthikumar around 1998 (Probab. Eng. Inf. Sci. 12:1–23, 1998). Subsequent to this, much has been written on it, mostly by Shaked and his colleagues; see Sordo (Insur. Math. Econ. 45(3):466–469, 2009) for a recent review. These works have appeared in the literatures of reliability theory and stochastic orderings. Since the term excess wealth connotes a measure of income inequality—much like its dual, poverty—it should have had an impact in economics and the econometric literature. This, it appears is not the case, at least to the extent that it should be. The purpose of this paper is to investigate the above disconnect by looking at the notion of excess wealth more carefully, but keeping in mind the angle of economics and income. Our conclusion is that an alternative definition of excess wealth better encapsulates what one means by a colloquial use of the term.

Our motivation for being attracted to this topic arises from two angles. The first is that the stochastics of diagnostic and threat detection tests, in which we have an interest, has a strong bearing on indices of concentration like the Lorenz Curve, the Gini index, and the entropy. Thus the notion of excess wealth, which conveys a sense of income concentration should also be relevant to diagnostics. The second motivation is to honor Moshe Shaked, a prolific researcher and a friend of the first author, by developing a paper based on an idea that is co-attributed to him.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Basu, A., Shioya, H., & Park, C. (2011). Monographs on statistics and applied probability: Vol. 120. Statistical inference: the minimum distance approach. Boca Raton: Chapman & Hall/CRC Press, Taylor & Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandra, M., & Singpurwalla, N. D. (1981). Relationships between some notions which are common to reliability theory and economics. Mathematics of Operations Research, 6(1), 113–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiuoli, E., Pellerey, F., & Shaked, M. (1999). A characterization of the dilation order and its application. Statistical Papers, 40(4), 393–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu, T., Wang, Y., & Zhuang, W. (2012). New properties of the total time on test transform order. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 26, 43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys, P. (1985). Why propensities cannot be probabilities. The Philosophical Review, 94, 557–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kochar, S., Li, X., & Shaked, M. (2002). The total time on test transform and the excess wealth stochastic orders of distributions. Advances in Applied Probability, 34(4), 826–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindley, D. V., & Phillips, L. D. (1976). Inference for a Bernoulli process (a Bayesian view). American Statistician, 30, 112–119.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popper, K. R. (1959). The propensity interpretation of probability. British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 10(37), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarabia, J. M. (2008). A general definition of the Leimkuhler curve. Journal of Infometrics, 2, 156–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaked, M., & Shanthikumar, J. G. (1998). Two variability orders. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 12, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singpurwalla, N. D. (2006). Reliability and risk: a Bayesian perspective. West Sussex: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sordo, M. A. (2009). Comparing tail variabilities of risks by means of the excess wealth order. Insurance. Mathematics & Economics, 45(3), 466–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge the several helpful comments by Professor Shaked which have resulted in the current version of this paper. Professor Nikolai Kolev drew attention to the Leimkuhler Curve. Research supported by the Army Research Office grant W911NF-09-1-0039, and by the National Science Foundation grant DMS-09-15156, with The George Washington University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nozer D. Singpurwalla.

Appendix: Exploring the normalized excess wealth function

Appendix: Exploring the normalized excess wealth function

Recall that the normalized excess wealth function is given by the equation

$$EW_F^*(p)=\frac{\int_p^1F^{-1}(u)\,\mathrm{d}u-(1-p)F^{-1}(p)}{\mu},\quad 0\leq p\leq1, $$

where F is the distribution function of income in a population.

Given below are plots of the normalized excess wealth function for several distributions. For some distributions these are calculated analytically, but for others these were obtained by simulation.

1.1 A.1 A uniform distribution

Suppose that F is a uniform distribution on the interval [0,1]. Then the excess wealth function is

$$\int_p^1u\,\mathrm{d}u-(1-p)p=\frac{p^2}{2}-p+ \frac{1}{2}. $$

Multiplying by 2 to normalize the excess wealth function, we get

$$EW_F^*(p)=p^2-2p+1,\quad 0\leq p\leq1, $$

which is a strictly convex function of p—see Fig. 16.

Fig. 16
figure 16

The normalized excess wealth function for a uniform distribution

1.2 A.2 An exponential distribution

Suppose that F is an exponential distribution with mean 1. Then the excess wealth function is

$$\int_p^1-\log(1-u)\,\mathrm{d}u+(1-p) \log (1-p)=(1-p). $$

Normalizing the above we get

$$EW_F^*(p)=1-p,\quad 0\leq p\leq1, $$

a straight line with slope =−1. Technically this is both a convex and a concave function.

1.3 A.3 A Weibull distribution with shape <1

Suppose F is a Weibull distribution with a scale parameter =1 and a shape parameter =.5, denoted Weibull(1,.5). Then

The excess wealth function is

Normalizing this function we get

$$EW_F^*(p)=-(1-p)\log (1-p)+(1-p),\quad 0\leq p\leq1, $$

which is a strictly concave function of p—see Fig. 17.

Fig. 17
figure 17

The normalized excess wealth function for a Weibull(1,.5) distribution

1.4 A.4 A Pareto distribution

Suppose that F is a Pareto type II distribution with location parameter =1, and shape parameter =2. For this distribution, \(EW_{F}^{*}\) was obtained by simulation. It is illustrated in Fig. 18 as a strictly concave function of p.

Fig. 18
figure 18

The normalized excess wealth function of a Pareto type II distribution

1.5 A.5 A Weibull distribution with shape >1

Suppose that F is a Weibull distribution with scale parameter =1, and shape parameter =2. Then \(EW_{F}^{*}\), obtained by simulation, is illustrated in Fig. 19. Here the normalized excess wealth function is convex in p.

Fig. 19
figure 19

The normalized excess wealth function for a Weibull(1,2) distribution

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Singpurwalla, N.D., Gordon, A.S. Auditing Shaked and Shanthikumar’s ‘excess wealth’. Ann Oper Res 212, 3–19 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-012-1202-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-012-1202-6

Keywords

Navigation