Skip to main content
Log in

A market-consistent framework for the fair evaluation of insurance contracts under Solvency II

  • Published:
Decisions in Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The entry into force of the Solvency II regulatory regime is pushing insurance companies in engaging into market consistence evaluation of their balance sheet, mainly with reference to financial options and guarantees embedded in life with-profit funds. The robustness of these valuations is crucial for insurance companies in order to produce sound estimates and good risk management strategies, in particular, for liability-driven products such as with-profit saving and pension funds. This paper introduces a Monte Carlo simulation approach for evaluation of insurance assets and liabilities, which is more suitable for risk management of liability-driven products than common approaches generally adopted by insurance companies, in particular, with respect to the assessment of valuation risk.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. IFRS 17 is effective from 1 January 2021. A company can choose to apply IFRS 17 before that date, but only if it also applies IFRS 9 Financial Instruments and IFRS 15 Revenue from Contracts with Customers. The board will support the implementation of IFRS 17 over the next three and half years.

  2. See definition (7) (Commission 2015), insurance and reinsurance undertakings’ valuation of the assets and liabilities using the market-consistent valuation methods prescribed in international accounting standards adopted by the Commission in accordance with Regulation (EC) No. 1606/2002, should follow a valuation hierarchy with quoted market prices in active markets for the same assets or liabilities being the default valuation method in order to ensure that assets and liabilities are valued at the amount for which they could be exchanged in the case of assets or transferred or settled in the case of liabilities between knowledgeable and willing parties in an arm’s length transaction. This approach should be applied by undertakings regardless of whether international or other valuation methods follow a different valuation hierarchy.

  3. The estimates of future cash flows shall be current, explicit, unbiased and reflect all the information available to the entity without undue cost and effort about the amount, timing and uncertainty of those future cash flows. They should reflect the perspective of the entity, provided that the estimates of any relevant market variables are consistent with observable market prices [IFRS 17:33, Measurement].

  4. See data on life insurance market at https://www.insuranceeurope.eu/insurancedata.

  5. For a comprehensive introduction to ESGs and their applications to insurance and pension funds, see SOA (2016).

  6. By and large, liability-driven investments are saving or pension products, like segregated fund, where the way assets performance affects liabilities is critical for the sustainability and success of the investment strategy.

  7. For the definition of equivalent martingale measure and the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, see for example Bjork (2009).

  8. In market-consistent evaluations, liability cash flows are discounted using a risk-free curve derived from six months Euribor, which is constructed as prescribed by EIOPA. After the financial crisis in 2008, some European sovereign bond issuers (as Portugal, Italy, Greece and Spain) began to trade with a material spread over Euribor. Therefore, the assets of many insurance companies began to deteriorate while liabilities did not due to the basis or liquidity effect between market prices and discounting factors used to assess the economic value of technical provisions.

  9. At the heart of the prudential Solvency II directive, the own risk and solvency assessment (ORSA) is defined as a set of processes constituting a tool for decision-making and strategic analysis. It aims to assess, in a continuous and prospective way, the overall solvency needs related to the specific risk profile of the insurance company.

  10. With valuation risk, we mean correlation, basis, liquidity and model risks in accordance with the prudent person principle as stated in the article 132 of Solvency II Directive.

  11. For an overview of insurance participating contracts, see Pitacco (2012).

  12. See, for example, the hedging requirement under IFRS 9 financial instruments.

  13. A stochastic time is a real positive and increasing right continuous process with left limits, for every \(t \ge 0\), \(\tau (t)\) is a stopping time, \(\tau (t)\) is finite almost surely, \(\tau (0) = 0\) and \(\lim \nolimits _{t \rightarrow \infty } \tau (t) = \infty \) (see Barndorff-Nielsen and Shiryaev 2010 for a complete discussion).

  14. The relevance of the Italian traditional with-profit business as an example is explained in Gambaro et al. (2018). The same paper includes more information on the certainty equivalent and the market-consistent approach to insurance valuations.

  15. A consequence of an higher turnover on the assets portfolio is the reduction of unrealised gains (or losses), which are used by insurance companies to steer the performance credited to and shared with the policyholder.

Abbreviations

ALM:

Assets and liabilities management

CDF:

Cumulative distribution function

CDS:

Credit default swap

CEQ:

Certainty equivalent

CFO:

Chief financial officers

CIR:

Cox Ingersoll Ross

EIOPA:

European Insurance and Occupational Pension Authority

ESG:

Economic scenario generator

IASB:

International Accounting Standards Board

IFRS:

International Financial Reporting Standard

LGAAP:

Local generally accepted accounting principle

MCEV:

Market Consistent Embedded Value

ORSA:

Own risk and solvency assessment

SCR:

Solvency capital requirement

SDE:

Stochastic differential equation

VOG:

Value of guarantee

ZCB:

Zero coupon bond

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anna Maria Gambaro.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

A Change of measure derivation

The dynamics of r(t) under the real-world \(\mathbb {P}\) measure follows a Vasicek dynamics as in Sect. 3.3 Eq. (14)

$$\begin{aligned} dr(t)= & {} a \, (\bar{r} - r(t)) dt +\sigma \, dW^{\mathbb {P}}(t), \end{aligned}$$

where \(W^{\mathbb {P}}\) is a Brownian motion under the measure \(\mathbb {P}\). We define the Radon–Nykodim derivatives from the real-world measure \(\mathbb {P}\) to the risk-neutral measure \(\mathbb {Q}\) as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d \, \mathbb {Q}}{d \, \mathbb {P}} (t) = e^{-\frac{1}{2} \int _0^t m^2(s) \mathrm{d}s + \int _0^t m(s) \mathrm{d}W^{\mathbb {P}}(s) } \end{aligned}$$

where m(t) is the market price of interest rate risk, which has the following form

$$\begin{aligned} m(t) = \frac{\theta (t) - a \bar{r}}{\sigma }, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\theta (t)\) a deterministic function of time.

By Girsanow theorem, the short rate r(t) has the following dynamics under the risk-neutral \(\mathbb {Q}\) measure

$$\begin{aligned} dr(t)= & {} (\theta (t)-a r(t)) dt +\sigma dW(t), \end{aligned}$$

where W(t) is a Brownian motion under \(\mathbb {Q}\). The previous process is an Hull–White process, and it can be written as in Eq. (1) for conveniently chosen functions \(\alpha (t)\) and \(\theta (t)\) (see, for instance, Brigo and Mercurio 2006, pp. 72–73).

As in Sect. 3 the default risk of sovereign issuers is modelled using an intensity model (also called Cox processes or doubling stochastic Poisson processes) with intensities modelled using correlated CIR processes, for \(i=1,2,\ldots ,I\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\tau _i = \inf \left\{ t \ge 0: \int _0^t \lambda _i(s) \mathrm{d}s > \xi _i \right\} ,\\&dy_{i}(t) = b_i \left( \bar{s}_i - y_{i}(t) \right) dt + \eta _i \sqrt{y_{i}(t)} \, dZ^\mathbb {P}_i(t), \\&dZ^\mathbb {P}_i(t) \, dZ^\mathbb {P}_j(t) = \rho _{ij} \, dt, \end{aligned}$$

where I is the number of sovereign bond issuers, \(\tau _i\) is the stochastic time of default of the ith issuer, \(\xi _i\) are i.i.d. unitary exponential random variables and \(Z^\mathbb {P}(t)\) ia a I-dimensional Brownian motions under \(\mathbb {P}\).

By Girsanov theorem for point processes (Bremaud 1981), defining the Radon–Nykodim derivatives as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d \, \mathbb {Q}}{d \, \mathbb {P}} (t) = \prod _{i=1}^I \left( \prod _{n \ge 1} \left( 1+ \frac{\psi _i(t)}{y_i(t)}\right) \text {I}(\tau _i(n) \le t)\right) e^{\int _0^t \psi _i(s) \, \mathrm{d}s}, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\psi _i(t)\) deterministic functions of time, we obtain that the credit risk intensity of the i-th issuer under the risk- neutral probability is

$$\begin{aligned} s_i(t) = \psi _i(t) + y_i(t), \end{aligned}$$

where \(y_i(t)\) follows the process in Eq. (5).

By similar reasoning, using the point process Girsanov theorem, the dynamics of the corporate credit risk intensity changes from the real-world process as in Eq. (15) to the risk- neutral measure process as in Eq. (12).

B Maximum likelihood for default probabilities

In this section, we detail the procedure used to calibrate the CIR parameters via maximum likelihood method for the historical series of corporate default probabilities. The same procedure is applied to historical series of sovereign probabilities bootstrapped from CDS spreads. Let \(\theta \) be the set of the model parameters. We define

$$\begin{aligned} f(\lambda ; \theta ) := \varPi (t,T)_{iK}, \end{aligned}$$
(17)

and we assume that the function f is invertible with respect to \(\lambda = \lambda (t)\). Once we fix a maturity \(\tau \) and an initial rate i, then we can build the historical series of default probabilities \(\{\varPi _1,\ldots ,\varPi _N\}\) where \(\varPi _n = \varPi (t_n, t_n+\tau )_{iK}\). The likelihood function of the observed default probabilities is

$$\begin{aligned} L(\varPi _1,\ldots ,\varPi _N | \theta ) = \prod _{n=1}^N h_\varPi (\varPi _n;\theta ) \end{aligned}$$
(18)

where \(h_\varPi (x;\theta )\) is the conditional density function of the default probabilities (we assume that \(\varPi _1,\ldots ,\varPi _N\) are i.i.d.). The default probability density function \(h_\varPi \) can be obtained from the density function of \(\lambda \), which is a non-central Chi-squared distribution, using the monotonic transformation of random variables, as suggested in Pearson and Sun (1994), in the following way

$$\begin{aligned} h_\varPi (\varPi _n; \theta )= & {} h_{\lambda }(\lambda ^*_n ; \theta ) \, \frac{\partial f^{-1}}{\partial \varPi }(\varPi _n; \theta ) \\= & {} h_{\lambda }(\lambda ^*_n; \theta ) \, \left( \frac{\partial f}{\partial \lambda }(\lambda ^*_n; \theta )\right) ^{-1} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda ^*_n = f^{-1}(\varPi _n,\theta )\). Hence, a maximum likelihood estimator of the parameters is

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\theta } = \text {arg}\max _{\theta } L(\varPi _1,\ldots ,\varPi _N | \theta ) = \text {arg}\max _{\theta } \prod _{n=1}^N h_{\lambda }(\lambda ^*_n; \theta ) \, \left( \frac{\partial f}{\partial \lambda }(\lambda ^*_n; \theta )\right) ^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$

C Invariant probabilistic sensitivity analysis

Let y be a function of the model parameters (for instance, y can be the VOG)

$$\begin{aligned} y(\theta ) : D \rightarrow \mathbb {R}. \end{aligned}$$

with \(\theta \in D \subseteq \mathbb {R}^n\) and n is the number of the model parameters.

Let \(\varTheta \) be a random vector and \(\theta \) is realization, hence \(Y= y(\varTheta )\) is the corresponding random model output and \(F_Y\) is the CDF of Y.

We define the importance measure of \(\theta _i\) with respect to Y as

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _i = \mathbb {E}\left[ d(F_Y, F_{Y | \varTheta _i = \theta _i}) \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(0<d<1\) is a distance between the unconditional and the conditional CDF. We choose to use the Kuiper’s metric, then

$$\begin{aligned} d(F_Y, F_{Y | \varTheta _i = \theta _i}) = \sup _y \left( F_Y(y) - F_{Y | \varTheta _i = \theta _i}(y) \right) + \sup _y \left( F_{Y | \varTheta _i = \theta _i}(y) - F_Y(y) \right) . \end{aligned}$$

In Table 5, we report the values of the importance measures \(\beta _i\). A value near to one of \(\beta _i\) signals an important difference between \(F_Y\) and \(F_{Y | \varTheta _i = \theta _i}\), i.e. the parameter \(\theta _i\) is a “critical” parameter of the model.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gambaro, A.M., Casalini, R., Fusai, G. et al. A market-consistent framework for the fair evaluation of insurance contracts under Solvency II. Decisions Econ Finan 42, 157–187 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10203-019-00242-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10203-019-00242-1

Keywords

Navigation