Skip to main content
Log in

Choice, habit and evolution

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several leading mainstream economists including Gary Becker have treated habit as serially correlated behaviour resulting from deliberate choices. This approach puts choice before habit but involves assumptions of extensive memory and decision-making capacity. By contrast, earlier authors such as William James, John Dewey and Thorstein Veblen saw deliberation and choice as a contingent outcome of habits, where the latter are defined in terms of acquired dispositions rather than overt behaviour. The approach of this second group is more consistent with an evolutionary perspective and the limited computational capacities of the human brain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The author is grateful to an anonymous referee and participants at an Erfurt workshop on ‘Automaticity in Judgement and Decision Making’, 28 February–1 March 2008, for comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

  2. In contrast, in a early paper Becker (1962) regarded rationality and habit as rival but similarly competent explanations of economic phenomena: habit was not explained in terms of rationality. After his meta-preference function appeared in later writings its intended ontological status remained unclear. Becker might follow Milton Friedman (1953) in proposing that the only scientific test of such a function is whether it makes ‘correct predictions’. This leaves unanswered the vital question of what viable neural and psychological mechanisms actually underlie preferences or choice.

  3. Of course, limited human computational capacity was a key issue raised by Herbert Simon (1957). Ironically, despite their overall focus on the concept of scarcity, neoclassical economists are led by their stress on rationality to overlook scarce mental capacities. For a long while, the adoption of Robbin’s (1932) strictures and Friedman’s (1953) ‘as if’ methodology diverted economists from consideration of the neural and psychological realities underpinning preferences. Fortunately, economists are now paying more attention to psychology (Rabin 1998).

  4. The tide of opinion became so strong that many who claimed to be disciples of Veblen—notably Clarence Ayres (1921a, b)—eschewed the concept of instinct for the social sciences. Such views of instinct remained so influential for so long that even Hayek (1988, pp. 16–17), who increasingly adopted ideas from biology, believed that a ‘gradual replacement of innate responses by learnt rules increasingly distinguished man from other animals’ and typically regarded instincts as ‘atavistic’, ‘ferocious’ or ‘beastly’.

  5. Nevertheless, Libet (2004) argues that his experimental evidence is consistent with free will, which can intervene to block actions already foreshadowed in brain processes. Whether free will is consistent with the fact that our will is itself caused is an old philosophical controversy. To a large degree it depends on what precisely is meant by ‘free will’ (Dennett 1984).

  6. See Bunge (1980), Stich (1983), Churchland (1984, 1986, 1989), Damasio (1994), Rosenberg (1995, 1998), Kilpinen (2000).

  7. By contrast, some economists see choice as an ‘uncaused cause’ (Shackle 1976) or uphold a view of human agency as ‘free of external causes’ (Minkler 2008, p. 21). For a critique of such claims of ‘uncaused causes’ see Hodgson (2004, pp. 61–2, 87–9).

  8. Figure 2 neglects the important proposal by evolutionary psychologists Cosmides and Tooby (1994a, b) that the brain is not an all-purpose calculator but segmented or ‘modularized’. Incorporation of this insight would require significant further development and complication of the figure.

References

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2005) Identity and the economics of organizations. J Econ Perspect 19(1):9–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1986) Rationality of self and others in an economic system. J Bus 59(4.2):S385–S399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1994) Methodological individualism and social knowledge. Am Econ Rev (Papers and Proceedings) 84(2):1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayres CE (1921a) Instinct and capacity—I: the instinct of belief-in-instincts. J Philos 18(21):561–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres CE (1921b) Instinct and capacity—II: Homo Domesticus. J Philos 18(22):600–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1962) Irrational behavior and economic theory. J Polit Econ 70(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1976) Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: economics and sociobiology. J Econ Lit 14(2):817–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1992) Habits, addictions and traditions. Kyklos 45:327–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) ‘A theory of rational addiction’. J Polit Econ 96(4):675–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (1998) Endogenous preferences: the cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. J Econ Lit 36(1):75–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (2004) Microeconomics: behavior, institutions, and evolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Bunge MA (1980) The mind-body problem: a psychobiological approach. Pergamon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvin WH (2002) A brain for all seasons: human evolution and abrupt climate change. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Camic C (1986) The matter of habit. Am J Sociol 91(5):1039–1087

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Churchland PM (1984) Matter and consciousness. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Churchland PM (1989) A neurocomputational perspective: the nature of mind and the structure of science. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Churchland PS (1986) Neurophilosophy: toward a unified science of the mind-brain. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chomsky N (1959) Review of verbal behavior by B. F. Skinner. Language 35:26–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley CH (1922) Human nature and the social order, 2nd edn. Scribner’s, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cosmides L, Tooby J (1994a) Beyond intuition and instinct blindness: towards an evolutionary rigorous cognitive science. Cognition 50(1–3):41–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cosmides L, Tooby J (1994b) Better than rational: evolutionary psychology and the invisible hand. Am Econ Rev (Papers and Proceedings) 84(2):327–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Damasio AR (1994) Descartes’ error: emotion, reason, and the human brain. Putnam, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Darwin CR (1859) On the origin of species by means of natural selection, or the preservation of favoured races in the struggle for life, 1st edn. Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Darwin CR (1871) The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex, 1st edn, 2 vols. Hill, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Darwin CR (1974) Metaphysics, materialism, and the evolution of mind: early writings of Charles Darwin, transcribed and annotated by Paul H. Barrett with a commentary by Howard E. Gruber. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Degler CN (1991) In search of human nature: the decline and revival of Darwinism in American social thought. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennett DC (1984) Elbow room: the varieties of free will worth wanting. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey J (1894) The ego as cause. Philos Rev 3(3):337–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewey J (1922) Human nature and conduct: an introduction to social psychology, 1st edn. Holt, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Drubach D (2000) The brain explained. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Durkheim É (1984) The Division of Labour in Society, translated from the French edition of 1893 by W. D. Halls with an introduction by Lewis Coser. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1953) ‘The Methodology of Positive Economics’. In: Friedman M (ed) Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 3–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Giddings FH (1896) The principles of sociology: an analysis of the phenomena of association and of social organization. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hands DW (2001) Reflection without rules: economic methodology and contemporary science theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1988) The fatal conceit: the errors of socialism. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Haynes J-D, Rees G (2005a) Predicting the orientation of invisible stimuli from activity in human primary visual cortex. Nat Neurosci 8(5):686–691

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haynes J-D, Rees G (2005b) Predicting the stream of consciousness from activity in human visual cortex. Curr Biol 15(14):1301–1307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haynes J-D, Sakai K, Rees G, Gilbert S, Frith C, Passingham R (2007) Reading hidden intentions in the human brain. Curr Biol 17(4):323–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobson JA (1914) Work and wealth: a human valuation. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (1988) Economics and institutions: a manifesto for a modern institutional economics. Polity, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (1997) The ubiquity of habits and rules. Camb J Econ 21(6):663–684

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2004) The evolution of institutional economics: agency, structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2006a) Economics in the shadows of Darwin and Marx: essays on institutional and evolutionary themes. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2006b) Instinct and habit before reason: comparing the views of John Dewey, friedrich hayek and thorstein veblen. Adv Austrian Econ 9:109–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2007a) Institutions and individuals: interaction and evolution. Organ Stud 28(1):95–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2007b) Meanings of methodological individualism. J Econ Methodol 14(2):211–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2008) Prospects for economic sociology. Philos Soc Sci 38(1):133–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2004) The complex evolution of a simple traffic convention: the functions and implications of habit. J Econ Behav Organ 54(1):19–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huxley TH (1894) Collected essays, 9 vols. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • James W (1893) The principles of psychology, 2nd edn. Holt, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Joas H (1996) The Creativity of Action, translated from the German edition of 1992. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Kilpinen E (2000) The enormous fly-wheel of society: Pragmatism’s habitual conception of action and social theory. University of Helsinki, Helsinki

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight FH (1924) ‘The Limitations of Scientific Method in Economics’. In: Tugwell RG (ed) The trend of economics. Alfred Knopf, New York, pp 229–267

    Google Scholar 

  • Libet B (1985) Unconscious cerebral initiative and the role of conscious will in voluntary action. Behav Brain Sci 8:529–566

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libet B (2004) Mind time: the temporal factor in consciousness. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Libet B, Gleason CA, Wright EW, Pearl DK (1983) Time of conscious intention to act in relation to onset of cerebral activity (readiness-potential): the unconscious initiation of a freely voluntary act. Brain 106(3):623–642

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margolis H (1987) Patterns, thinking and cognition: a theory of judgment. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayr E (1988) Toward a new philosophy of biology: observations of an evolutionist. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayr E (1991) One long argument: Charles Darwin and the Genesis of Modern Evolutionary Thought. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Minkler LP (2008) Integrity and agreement: economics when principles also matter. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy JB (1994) ‘The kinds of order in society’. In: Mirowski P (ed) Natural images in economic thought: “Markets Read in Tooth and Claw”. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 536–582

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1994) Economic performance through time. Am Econ Rev 84(3):359–567

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouellette JA, Wood W (1998) Habit and intention in everyday life: the multiple processes by which past behavior predicts future behavior. Psychol Bull 124:54–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons T (1937) The structure of social action, 2 vols. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinker S (1994) The language instinct: the new science of language and mind. Allen Lane and Morrow, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Plotkin HC (1994) Darwin machines and the nature of knowledge: concerning adaptations, instinct and the evolution of intelligence. Penguin, Harmondsworth

    Google Scholar 

  • Poldrack RA, Clark J, Pare-Blagoev J, Shohamy D, Creso Moyano J, Myers C, Gluck MA (2001) Interactive memory systems in the human brain. Nature 414(29):546–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potts R (1996) Humanity’s descent: the consequences of ecological instability. William Morrow, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin M (1998) Psychology and economics. J Econ Lit 36(1):11–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Rayo L, Becker GS (2007) Evolutionary efficiency and happiness. J Polit Econ 115(2):302–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richerson PJ, Boyd R (2001) Built for speed, not for comfort: Darwinian theory and human culture. Hist Philos Life Sci 23(3/4):423–463

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins L (1932) An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson I (1978) Sociology: an introduction. Worth, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg A (1995) The philosophy of social science, 2nd edn. Westview, Boulder

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg A (1998) ‘Folk psychology’. In: Davis JB, Hands DW, Mäki U (eds) Handbook of economic methodology. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 195–197

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackle GLS (1976) Time and choice. Proc Br Acad 66:309–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1957) Models of man: social and rational. Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Stich SP (1983) From folk psychology to cognitive science. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg VJ (2002) Rational choice versus program-based behavior: alternative theoretical approaches and their relevance for the study of institutions. Ration Soc 14(1):7–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg VJ (2004) The rationality postulate in economics: its ambiguity, its deficiency and its evolutionary alternative. J Econ Methodol 11(1):1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen TB (1898) Why is economics not an evolutionary science? Q J Econ 12(3):373–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen TB (1914) The instinct of workmanship, and the state of the industrial arts. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward LF (1903) Pure sociology: a treatise on the origin and spontaneous development of society. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson JB (1924) Behaviorism. W. W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wegner DM (2002) The illusion of conscious will. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Wegner DM (2003) The mind’s best trick: how we experience conscious will. Trends Cogn Sci 7(2):65–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wegner DM, Wheatley T (1999) Apparent mental causation: sources of the experience of the will. Am Psychol 54:480–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood W, Neal DT (2007) A new look at habits and the habit-goal interface. Psychol Rev 114(4):843–863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood W, Quinn JM, Kashy D (2002) Habits in everyday life: thought, emotion, and action. J Pers Soc Psychol 83:1281–1297

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Geoffrey M. Hodgson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hodgson, G.M. Choice, habit and evolution. J Evol Econ 20, 1–18 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0134-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-009-0134-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation