Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Labor market institutions and industrial performance: an evolutionary study

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates the impact of labor market institutions on industrial performance from a Schumpeterian perspective. We suggest that labor market institutions play a very important role in the process of creative destruction, because they may create an environment that encourages and enforces innovation, and help to reallocate resources, most importantly labor, through swift elimination of weak performers. We specifically look at the effects of the quantity of labor market regulations and inter-industry wage differentials on labor productivity for a panel of 44 countries for the period 1965–1999. Our findings suggest that those countries that introduce more regulations on conditions of employment and wages achieve higher levels of productivity. Moreover, wage compression raises productivity by reallocating resources to productive activities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. However, their study is likely to suffer from very low variation in the labor regulation variable (no change over time in six out of 16 states).

  2. Delmas (2002), in her study on seven European countries, claims that “labor regulations … can sometimes discourage innovation”, but did not include in the estimated model any variable measuring the extent of labor regulations.

  3. See Natlex homepage, http://natlex.ilo.org.

  4. See the LMRI website for more information: http://www.metu.edu.tr/~etaymaz/lmri.

  5. A country is classified as HIC (LIC) if its GNI per-capita was greater (less) than $9205 in 1999 (for the GNI per-capita data, see World Bank 2002).

  6. We do not present separately the figures for other labor market regulation indices because the patterns are rather similar.

  7. Since all variables used in the model are persistent, and change gradually over time, we use the average values of the variables for 5-year intervals. This method also mitigates the effects of measurement errors and annual fluctuations.

  8. The capital stock is calculated by perpetual inventory method from the UNIDO database (UNIDO 2002). The depreciation rate is assumed to be 7.5 percent.

  9. Note that the exchange rate does not have any effect on regression results because all country specific effects are accounted for by fixed effects, α i s, in the model.

  10. Specialized-supplier and science-based industries include Office and Computing Machinery (ISIC-3822), Machinery and Equipment, nec. (ISIC-382X), Radio, TV and Communication Equipment (ISIC-3832), Electrical Machinery, nec. (ISIC 383X), and Professional Goods (ISIC 385).

  11. We do not include variables on other possible sources of growth (human capital, R&D, and so on.) since those are beyond the scope of this study. We experimented with human capital proxied by primary and secondary school enrolment, and youth and adult illiteracy rates in our estimations, but we decided to exclude these variables basically for two reasons. First, the human capital data are not available for 1960s for most of the countries. Second, the coefficients of these variables were insignificant in many cases.

  12. Of course, this does not mean that any increase in the number of labor market regulations leads to productivity improvement. The results imply that LMRs included in the Natlex Database from 1960 to 1999 seem to have a positive impact on productivity for our sample of countries.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Pischke JS (1999a) Beyond becker: training in imperfect labor markets. Econ J 109:112–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Pischke JS (1999b) The structure of wages and investment in general training. J Polit Econ 107:539–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agell J (1999) On the benefits from rigid labour markets: norms, market failures, and social insurance. Econ J 109:F143–F164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt T, Tzannatos Z (2002) Unions and collective bargaining, economic effects in a global environment. World Bank, Washington DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alexopoulos M, Cohen J (2003) Centralised wage bargaining and structural change in Sweden. Eur Rev Econ Hist 7:331–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam W, Booth AL (1998) Training and labour market flexibility: is there a trade-off? Br J Ind Relat 36:521–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballot G, Fakhfakh F, Taymaz E (2006) Who benefits from training and R&D, the firm or the workers? Br J Ind Relat 44:473–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassanini A, Ernst E (2002) Labour market regulation, industrial relations and technological regimes: a tale of comparative advantage. Ind Corp Change 11:391–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Burgess R (2004) Can labor regulation hinder economic performance? Evidence from India. Q J Econ 119:91–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Lynch LM (2004) What’s driving the new economy?: the benefits of workplace innovation. Econ J 114:F97–F116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botero J, Djankov S, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shliefer A (2004) The regulation of labor. Q J Econ 119:1339–1382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno GSF (2005) Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Econ Lett 87:361–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc P, Michel P (1996) Minimum wage unemployment and growth. Eur Econ Rev 40:1463–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cappelli P (2000) Examining the incidence of downsizing and its effect on establishment performance, NBER working paper no. 7742, Cambridge, MA: NBER.

  • Davis S (2001) The quality of distribution of jobs and the structure of wages in search equilibrium, NBER working paper no: 8434, Cambridge, MA: NBER

  • Davis SJ, Henrekson M (2005) Wage-setting institutions as industrial policy. Labour Econ 12:345–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delmas MA (2002) Innovating against European rigidities. Institutional environment and dynamic capabilities. J High Technol Managem Res 13:19–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg J (2002) Technology, growth and competitiveness: selected essays, Edward Elgar Publishing

  • Forteza A, Rama M (2006) Labor market ‘rigidity’ and the success of economic reforms across more than 100 countries. J Policy Reform 9:75–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RB (1988) Labour market institutions and economic performance. Econ Policy 3:63–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RB (2005) Labour market institutions without blinders: the debate over flexibility and labour market performance. Int Econ J 19:129–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gust C, Marquez J (2004) International comparisons of productivity growth: the role of information technology and regulatory practices. Labour Econ 11:33–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs DA Jr, Locking H (2000) Wage dispersion and productive efficiency: evidence for Sweden. J Labor Econ 18:755–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman AO (1970) Exit, voice, and loyalty: response to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass

    Google Scholar 

  • ILO (2002) Natlex database of national labour, social security and related human rights legislation, on CD

  • Kleinknecht A (1998) Is labour market flexibility harmful to innovation? Camb J Econ 22:387–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleinknecht A, Oostendorp RM, Pradhan MP, Naastepad CWM (2006) Flexible labour, firm performance and the dutch job creation miracle. Int Rev Appl Econ 20:171–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koeniger W (2005) Dismissal costs and innovation. Econ Lett 88:79–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenger A, Taymaz E (2006) To innovate or to transfer? A study on spillovers and foreign firms in Turkey. J Evol Econ 16:137–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michie J, Sheehan-Quinn M (2001) Labour market flexibility, human resource management and corporate performance. Br J Manage 12:287–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michie J, Sheehan M (2003) Labour market deregulation flexibility and innovation. Camb J Econ 27:123–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milberg W, Houston E (2005) The high road and the low road to international competitiveness: extending the neo-Schumpeterian trade model beyond technology. Int Rev Appl Econ 19:137–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell S and Nunziata L (2001) Labour Market Institutions Database, LMIDB: version 2.00, 1960–1995, unpublished paper, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE

  • Nicoletti G, Scarpetta S and Boylaud O (1999) Summary indicators of product market regulations with an extension to employment protection legislation. OECD Economics Department working paper no. 226, Paris: OECD

  • OECD (1986) Flexibility in the labour market: the current debate. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (1994) The OECD jobs study: facts, analysis, strategies. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Padovano F, Galli E (2003) Corporatism, policies and growth. Econ Gov 4:245–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rama M, Artecona R (2002) A database of labour market indicators across countries, unpublished manuscript. The World Bank, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers M, Vernon G (2002) Wage inequality and productivity growth: motivating carrots and crippling sticks, unpublished paper. Harris Manchester College, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala-I-Martin XX (1996) I just ran four million regressions, NBER working paper no. 6252, Cambridge, MA: NBER

  • Scarpetta S and Tressel T (2004) Boosting productivity via innovation and adoption of new technologies: any role for labor market institutions? World Bank policy research working paper 3273, Washington, DC: World Bank

  • Schumpeter JA (1950) Capitalism, socialism and democracy, 3rd edn. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Seguino S (2005) Is more mobility good? Firm mobility and the low wage–low productivity trap, Levy Economics Institute working paper no. 423, Annandale-on-Hudson, NY: Levy Economics Institute

  • UNIDO (2002) Industrial statistics database 3-digit level of ISIC, revision 2, on CD

  • World Bank (2002), World Development Indicators Database, on CD

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank two anonymous referees and Ali Cevat Taşıran of Göteborg University for their extremely helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erol Taymaz.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kılıçaslan, Y., Taymaz, E. Labor market institutions and industrial performance: an evolutionary study. J Evol Econ 18, 477–492 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-008-0098-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-008-0098-4

Keywords

JEL codes

Navigation