Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

On the dynamics of the age structure, dependency, and consumption

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the effects of population aging due to declining fertility and rising elderly life expectancy on consumption possibilities in the presence of intergenerational transfers. Our analysis is based on a highly tractable continuous-time overlapping generations model in which the population is divided into three groups (youth dependents, workers, and elderly dependents) and lifecourse transitions take place in a probabilistic fashion. We show that the consumption-maximizing response to greater longevity in highly developed countries is an increase in fertility. However, with larger transfer payments, the actual fertility response will likely be the opposite, leading to further population aging.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The mechanism that we examine here shares the feature of the model by Easterlin (1987) that reductions in living standards trigger compensating reductions in fertility. However, we focus on the fiscal effect of transfers to the elderly on after-tax earnings rather than on the effect of cohort size on the pre-tax wage of young workers—in principle, the two mechanisms could easily co-exist. The model by Cerda (2005) of social security crises is similar in spirit to ours, but our model permits a broader understanding of the interrelatedness of consumption possibilities and age structure.

  2. Gertler (1999) extends the model of Blanchard (1985), allowing for two age groups (working age and retired). Grafenhofer et al. (2007) present a model of probabilistic aging involving eight age groups, which they use to quantitatively assess the effects of population aging on savings, consumption, and the tax rate. Both models, however, take fertility as exogenous. Bommier and Lee (2003) develop a model of an economy with a continuous age distribution. They derive some interesting aggregate steady-state results, but make limited progress in analyzing aggregate dynamics.

  3. In our model, we ignore childhood and early-adult mortality, assuming that death occurs only among the retired. The model could easily be adapted to incorporate these other forms of mortality by changing the basic equations to:

    $$ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\dot{{A}}_{\rm Y} (t)=N(t)-(\lambda_Y +\mu_{\rm Y} )A_{\rm Y} (t),} \\[2pt] {\dot{{A}}_{\rm M} (t)=\lambda_{\rm Y} A_{\rm Y} (t)-(\lambda _{\rm M} +\mu_{\rm M} )A_{\rm M} (t),} \\[2pt] {\dot{{A}}_{\rm O} (t)=\lambda_{\rm M} A_{\rm M} (t)-\mu _{\rm O} A_{\rm O} (t).} \\ \end{array} } $$

    With this set-up, λ j is the transition probability to the next group, and μ j is the death rate in the group. Analysis of this model would parallel that in the main text, with qualitatively similar results.

  4. An additional set of equations, consistent with those governing the economic age structure, could be specified to allow ϕ to vary over time. However, such a specification results in a model that is substantially more complicated to analyze while adding very little qualitatively to our analysis.

  5. A companion paper (Hock and Weil 2007) considers the additional effects of changes in the retirement age.

  6. The GRR is the number of children individuals can expect to have, assuming that they are subject to the currently prevailing rate of fertility for the entirety of their childbearing years. Given our assumptions regarding the stock of fecund persons, the GRR works out to G = T F n = ϕT M n.

  7. A stable population is one in which the relative size of the age groups is constant. When fertility is at the replacement rate (G = 1), the equilibrium dependency ratios are \(\bar{{y}}^r=T_{Y} /T_{M} \) and \(\bar{{o}}^r=T_{O} /T_{M} \), paralleling basic results from stable population theory.

  8. The calculations in Hock and Weil (2007) use lifecycle consumption data from Japan and the United States as a benchmark and are derived from a simulated numerical analogue of the model presented here. Based on a range of mortality and retirement profiles that span what is observed in OECD member nations, consumption-maximizing fertility rates are generally well above replacement while actual fertility rates are substantially lower.

  9. In the United States, for example, life expectancy at age 65 has risen by approximately 3.5 years since 1950 (Board of Trustees, Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds 2005) and is projected to rise by an additional 4 years by 2050 (Lee and Carter 1992). Other highly developed countries have seen reductions in old-age mortality at least as large and can be expected to follow a similar trend in the future (Munnell et al. 2004).

  10. This can be established analytically since the marginal rate of demographic substitution rises for any value of y as T O increases.

  11. Kohler et al. (2002) provide a more comprehensive review.

  12. Although somewhat stylized, this distinction mirrors the substantial difference in the pattern of transfers to the old and young observed in highly developed countries. For example, private transfers account for over 61% of the transfer-based consumption of persons under age 20 in the United States, but only 11% of total transfers to persons over age 65 (Mason et al. 2009). One consequence of this assumption is that we abstract from a self-interested old-age support motive for childbearing of the type highlighted by Cigno (1992).

  13. Today, Japan is the best example of a country where falling population size interacts in a toxic fashion with a high level of per-capita government debt.

  14. Given the stochastic nature of aging in our model, parental payments are made upfront into a trust fund that pays for χ units of childcare services per period for the life of the child. To ensure that children always receive the requisite care, an actuarially neutral trust fund will set ξ = χ T Y /(1 − g T Y ), where g is the expected rate of wage growth. For the path of trust fund payments to remain bounded, g must be less than 1/ T Y . Taking 25 years as an upper limit on the average length of youth dependency, g must be less than 4% over the long run, which is in line with observed growth rates.

  15. A proof is available on request.

  16. In the case where all expenditures on children are privately funded, as in van Groezen et al. (2003), subsidies would be pegged to the child’s expected lifetime contribution to the pension system. In our model, child subsidies would be determined by the expected reduction in the tax burden associated with childbearing.

  17. Cerda (2005) describes a similar mechanism. However, in the absence of public transfers to the young in his model, low fertility may produce ever-rising payroll tax rates, eventually resulting in a social security melt-down.

  18. For analytic simplicity, we continue to treat public support for the young, α, as fixed and exogenous, although the model could accommodate bargaining over both parameters.

  19. In general, the \(\tilde{{Z}}_y (y)\) locus either stays below the horizontal axis or becomes undefined after the initial crossing; we ignore the trivial set of values of μ for which the locus would start to rise after meeting the horizontal axis.

  20. If the decisiveness parameter is less than one, then the multiplier effect on longevity will be amplified in the short run but dampened in the long run.

  21. It was not possible to analytically characterize the parameter configurations resulting in multiple equilibria, but numeric simulation yielded the configurations in Figs. 8 and 9 when using reasonable parameter values and a high value of μ.

  22. See Abel (2003) and Lim and Weil (2003).

References

  • Abel A (2003) The effects of a baby boom on stock prices and capital accumulation in the presence of social security. Econometrica 71(2):551–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adsera A (2005) Vanishing children: from high unemployment to low fertility in developed countries. Am Econ Rev 95(2):189–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach AJ, Kotlikoff LJ (1987) Dynamic fiscal policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OA (1985) Debt, deficits, and infinite horizons. J Polit Econ 93(2):223–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom DE, Canning D, Sevilla J (2001) Economic growth and the demographic transition. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8685, Cambridge, MA

  • Board of Trustees, Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability Trust Funds (2005) Annual report of the Board Of Trustees of the federal old-age and survivors insurance and disability insurance trust funds. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bommier A, Lee RD (2003) Overlapping generations models with realistic demography. J Popul Econ 16(1):135–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerda R (2005) On social security financial crises. J Popul Econ 18(3):509–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (1992) Children and pensions. J Popul Econ 5(3):175–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A, Rosati FC (1996) Jointly determined saving and fertility behaviour: theory and estimates for Germany, Italy, UK and USA. Eur Econ Rev 40(8):1561–1589

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler DM, Poterba JM, Sheiner LM, Summers LH, Akerlof GA (1990) An aging society: opportunity or challenge? Brookings Pap Econ Act 21(1):1–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Laat J, Sevilla-Sanz A (2011) Working women, men’s home time and lowest low fertility. Fem Econ 17(3)

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55(5):1126–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin RA (1987) Birth and fortune: the impact of numbers on personal welfare, 2nd edn. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Elmendorf DW, Sheiner LM (2000) Should America save for its old age? Fiscal policy, population aging, and national saving. J Econ Perspect 14(3):57–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Weil DN (1996) The gender gap, fertility, and growth. Am Econ Rev 86(3):374–387

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertler M (1999) Government debt and social security in a life-cycle economy. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 50(1):61–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein JR, Lutz W, Testa MR (2003) The emergence of sub-replacement family size ideals in Europe. Popul Res Policy Rev 22(5–6):479–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafenhofer D, Jaag C, Keuschnigg C, Keuschnigg M (2007) Economic ageing and demographic change. In: Lutz W (ed) Vienna yearbook of population research 2007. Austrian Academy of Sciences Press, Vienna, pp 133–165

    Google Scholar 

  • Grant J, Hoorens S, Sivadasan S, van het Loo M, DaVanzo J, Hale L, Gibson S, Butz W (2004) Low fertility and population ageing causes, consequences, and policy options. RAND Europe Leiden

  • Hirshleifer J (1989) Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice 63(2):101–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hock H, Weil DN (2007) Modeling the effects of population aging on consumption in the presence of intergenerational transfers. In: Clark R, Ogawa N, Mason A (eds) Population aging, intergenerational transfers and the macroeconomy. Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp 101–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler H-P, Billari FC, Ortega JA (2002) The emergence of lowest-low fertility in Europe during the 1990s. Popul Dev Rev 28(4):641–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee R, Carter LR (1992) Modeling and forecasting U.S. mortality. J Am Stat Assoc 87(419):659–671

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee RD, Edwards RD (2001) The fiscal impact of population change. In: Little JS, Triest RK (eds) Seismic shifts: the economic impact of demographic change. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, pp 189–219

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee RD, Lee S-H, Mason A (2008) Charting the economic life cycle. Popul Dev Rev 34(supp):207–237

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim K-M, Weil DN (2003) The baby boom and the stock market boom. Scand J Econ 105(3):359–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutz W, Skirbekk V, Testa MR (2007) The low fertility trap hypothesis: forces that may lead to further postponement and fewer births in Europe. In: Philipov D, Liefbroer AC, Billari FC (eds) Vienna yearbook of population research 2006. Austrian Academy of Sciences Press, Vienna, pp 167–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason A, Lee RD, Tung A-C, Li M-S, Miller T (2009) Population aging and intergenerational transfers: introducing age into national accounts. In: Wise D (ed) Developments in the economics of aging. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 89–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Munnell AH, Hatch RE, Lee JG (2004) Why Is life expectancy so low in the United States? Boston College, Center for Retirement Research Issues in Brief 21, Boston

  • Samuelson PA (1958) An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. J Polit Econ 66(6):467–482

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Groezen B, Leers T, Meijdam L (2003) Social security and endogenous fertility: pensions and child allowances as siamese twins. J Public Econ 87(2):233–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil DN (1999) Population growth, dependency, and consumption. Am Econ Rev 89(2):251–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wigger BU (1999) Pay-as-you-go financed public pensions in a model of endogenous growth and fertility. J Popul Econ 12(4):625–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (1995) Social security and endogenous growth. J Public Econ 58(2):185–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David N. Weil.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Junsen Zhang

Heinrich Hock acknowledges financial support for early work on this paper from an NICHD training grant (T32-HD07338) to the Population Studies and Training Center at Brown University. This paper has benefited from comments by participants at the Brown University Department of Economics Macro Lunch and the 2006 Conference on Population Aging, Intergenerational Transfers, and the Macroeconomy. We are particularly grateful to Alexia Prskawetz and two anonymous referees for valuable feedback. All errors are our own.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hock, H., Weil, D.N. On the dynamics of the age structure, dependency, and consumption. J Popul Econ 25, 1019–1043 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0372-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0372-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation