Skip to main content
Log in

Accounting quality, bank monitoring, and performance pricing loans

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We provide new evidence on the determinants of performance pricing provisions in bank loan contracts. We find that firms that are easier to monitor, such as those with better accounting quality, lower information opacity, or a stronger relationship with the lender are more likely to have performance pricing loans. The use of performance pricing is less likely after financial restatement events. Furthermore, we find that the likelihood of using accounting-based (as opposed to credit-rating-based) pricing provisions increases as the firm’s accounting quality increases, and as the strength of the prior lending relation increases. Our results are robust to alternative measures of accounting quality, information opacity, and bank monitoring, and suggest that monitoring costs have a significant impact on the design of debt contracts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Holthausen (1981), Leftwich (1981), Christie (1990), Watts and Zimmerman (1990), DeFond and Jiambalvo (1994), Sweeney (1994), and Dichev and Skinner (2002).

  2. Anecdotal evidence also supports this viewpoint. For instance, in 2006, creditors sued Adelphia Communications (which had performance-priced debt tied to leverage) to recover up to $187 million in interest payments. They claimed that Adelphia paid less interest than it should have because the leverage ratio it reported to lenders was lower than its true leverage ratio.

  3. We examine all performance pricing loans with performance measure of Debt/EBITDA ratio in Dealscan during 1990-2007, and find that the median grid in Debt/EBITDA is 0.5, i.e., the maximum distance of a borrower’s current Debt/EBITDA ratio to the performance pricing thresholds is 0.25. In contrast, the median distance between borrowers’ initial Debt/EBITDA ratio to their covenant thresholds for our sample firms is 1.00.

  4. Lenders care about managerial effort (or real firm performance) as well as financial reporting quality. In particular, lenders are worried about the effect of moral hazard on managerial effort. Being able to credibly contract on ex post performance should mitigate this concern. Therefore, an argument could be made here that lenders are more likely to issue a loan with pricing provisions tied to borrowers’ future performance if the borrowers’ managerial efforts are harder to monitor. However, lenders would worry about the effect of moral hazard on reporting quality as well. We argue here that if the borrowers’ financial reporting quality is harder to monitor (because of poorer accounting quality, more informational opacity, no prior lending relationship), then accounting numbers are less easily verifiable, and, therefore, less reliable. So the lender will not offer a loan with spreads tied to the borrower’s accounting numbers.

  5. We verify the robustness of our results using alternative accrual-based as well as non-accrual based measures of accounting quality. In particular, we use the standard deviation of residuals based on the original Dechow–Dichev model, the absolute value of residuals from both the Dechow–Dichev as well the modified Dechow–Dichev models, abnormal cash flows as in Roychowdhury (2006), and financial restatement events as alternative measures of accounting quality. These results are discussed in detail later in Sect. 4.

  6. Bharath et al. (2011) similarly capture opacity using firm size, availability of credit rating, S&P 500 inclusion, microstructure based measures, and analyst following. Flannery et al. (2004) use two proxies for firm opacity: the stock’s market microstructure properties and the ability of analysts to forecast firm earnings. Their market measures of the stock’s information opacity are the bid–ask spreads, trading activity, or return volatility.

  7. We do not differentiate between interest-increasing and interest-decreasing pricing provisions as do Asquith et al. because most of our loans are at the midpoint of the pricing grid and the loans could be interpreted as either interest- increasing or interest-decreasing.

  8. Roberts and Sufi (2009), however, find little evidence that the presence of performance pricing provision reduces the likelihood of renegotiation.

  9. For example, Kinney and McDaniel (1989), DeFond and Jiambalvo (1991), Palmrose et al. (2004), Palmrose and Scholz (2004), Graham et al. (2008), and Hutton et al. (2009).

  10. We start our sample in 1990 because the data before 1990 are not comprehensive and do not cover a majority of commercial loans.

  11. We keep the first restatement for each firm because we aim to examine the use of performance pricing provisions in loan contracts issued before and after restatement events, and the post-restatement window of the first restatement is likely to overlap with the pre-restatement window of (any) second restatement. This would be problematic in interpreting the results..

  12. Gomes and Phillips (2010), Maskara and Mullineaux (2011) construct information asymmetry index in a similar manner. It is computed as the average of the quintile ranking of a firm based on six information asymmetry measures (analyst forecast errors, dispersion of analyst opinions, volatility of residual returns, volatility of abnormal returns around earnings announcements, firm age, and bid-ask spreads).

  13. Similar to Anderson et al., to make data manageable, we focus on one-trading day every month (third Wednesday) and aggregate these 12 observations to get yearly bid-ask spread.

  14. The vast majority of our sample loans are syndicated loans, which typically involve two types of lenders: lead arrangers and participant lenders. Lead arrangers establish and maintain a relationship with the borrower, and take on the primary responsibility of information collection and monitoring. In contrast, participant lenders rarely directly negotiate with the borrowing firm. Lead arrangers are compensated with a fee for arranging and managing the syndicated loan, in addition to the loan interest and commitment fee income.

  15. Participant lenders rarely directly negotiate with the borrowing firm and usually hold a relatively small share of the loan.

  16. For example, in April 1998, First Union Corp. acquired CoreStates Financial Corp. with the merged entity being called ‘First Union Corp.’ Thus for the purpose of computing lead bank-borrower relation after April 1998, we assume that First Union Corp. inherited CoreStates’ entire lending history prior to April 1998.

  17. Although we call this variable BIG5 for convenience, the variable equals one in a given year if the firm’s auditors were any of the following: Arthur Andersen, Arthur Young, Coopers & Lybrand (this merged with Price Waterhouse on July 1, 1998), Ernst & Young, Deloitte & Touche, KPMG, PricewaterhouseCoopers (Price Waterhouse prior to July 1, 1998 merger with Coopers and Lybrand), or Touche Ross.

  18. Among the 7381 performance pricing loans, 422 loans involve more than one performance measure. This leaves us with 6959 performance pricing loans involving only one performance measure.

  19. We also find (results not tabulated in the interests of brevity) that performance pricing loans have longer maturity, are more likely to be a revolver, more likely to be secured and senior debt, more likely to have a financial or general covenant, and more likely to be syndicated relative to non-performance pricing loans.

  20. We get similar results when we use MDD_AQ 5, DD_AQ5, AMDD_AQ5, and ADD_5.

  21. Restatements might have positive or negative effect on income, and negative restatements are likely more indicative of low accounting quality. To investigate this conjecture, we identify whether a restatement has “Adverse” effect on financial statement from the Audit Analytics database. However we do not find any significant difference between restatements with and without “Adverse” effect on the likelihood of receiving performance pricing loans.

  22. Our results here are consistent with Bharath et al. (2008) who find that firms with poorer accounting quality take private rather than public debt. This is because public debt is associated with higher monitoring costs relative to private debt, and therefore, borrowers that are opaque or that have poorer accounting quality will find it costlier to take public debt..

  23. The Rating Dummy is equal to one if a firm has access to the public debt market, i.e., any type of S&P debt ratings is available in the Compustat database, and zero otherwise.

References

  • Anderson R, Duru A, Reeb D (2009) Founders, heirs, and corporate opacity in the U.S. J Financ Econ 92:205–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asquith P, Beatty A, Weber J (2005) Performance pricing in debt contracts. J Account Econ 40:101–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bae K, Goyal VK (2009) Creditor rights, enforcement, and bank loans. J Financ 64:823–860

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball R, Bushman R, Vasvari F (2008) The debt-contracting value of accounting information and loan syndicate structure. J Account Res 46:247–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty A, Weber J (2003) The effects of debt contracting on voluntary accounting method changes. Account Rev 78:119–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty A, Dichev ID, Weber J (2002) The role and characteristics of accounting-based performance pricing in private debt contracts. Emory University, Ohio State University, and MIT, Working Paper

  • Berger A, Udell G (1995) Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. J Bus 68:351–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Mullainathan S (1999) Is there discretion in wage setting? A test using takeover legislation. Rand J Econ 30:535–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Mullainathan S (2003) Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance and managerial preferences. J Polit Econ 111:1043–1075

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath S, Dahiya S, Saunders A, Srinivasan A (2007) So what do I get? The bank’s view of lending relationships. J Financ Econ 85:368–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath S, Sunder J, Sunder S (2008) Accounting quality and debt contracting. Account Rev 83:1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath S, Dahiya S, Saunders A, Srinivasan A (2011) Lending relationships and loan contract terms. Rev Financ Stud 24:1141–1203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chava S, Kumar P, Warga A (2010) Managerial agency and bond covenants. Rev Financ Stud 23:1120–1148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christie AA (1990) Aggregation of test statistics: an evaluation of the evidence on contracting and size hypotheses. J Account Econ 12:15–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Dichev I (2002) The quality of accruals and earnings: the role of accrual estimation errors. Account Rev 77:35–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeFond ML, Jiambalvo J (1991) Incidence and circumstances of accounting errors. Account Rev 66:643–655

    Google Scholar 

  • DeFond ML, Jiambalvo J (1994) Debt covenant violation and manipulation of accruals. J Account Econ 17:145–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeFond ML, Subramanyam KR (1998) Auditor changes and discretionary accruals. J Account Econ 25:35–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW (1991) Monitoring and reputation: the choice between bank loans and directly placed debt. J Polit Econ 99:689–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dichev ID, Skinner DJ (2002) Large-sample evidence on the debt covenant hypothesis. J Account Res 40:1091–1123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinc S (2000) Bank reputation, bank commitment, and the effects of competition in credit market. Rev Financ Stud 13:781–812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eng LL, Lin YC (2012) Accounting quality, earnings management and cross-listings: evidence from China. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 15:1250009–1–1250009-25

    Google Scholar 

  • Flannery MJ, Kwan SH, Nimalendran M (2004) Market evidence on the opaqueness of banking firms’ assets. J Financ Econ 71:419–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis JR, Krishnan J (1999) Accounting accruals and auditor reporting conservatism. Contemp Account Res 16:135–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis J, LaFond R, Olsson PM, Schipper K (2005) The market pricing of accruals quality. J Account Econ 39:295–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Teruel PJ, Martínez-Solano P, Sánchez-Ballesta JP (2014) The role of accruals quality in the access to bank debt. J Bank Financ 38:186–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes A, Phillips G (2010) Private and public security issuance by public firms: the role of asymmetric information. Working paper

  • Graham JR, Li S, Qiu J (2008) Corporate misreporting and bank loan contracting. J Financ Econ 89:44–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haubrich JG (1989) Financial intermediation: delegated monitoring and long-term relationships. J Bank Financ 13:9–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holthausen RW (1981) Evidence on the effect of bond covenants and management compensation contracts on the choice of accounting techniques: the case of the depreciation switch-back. J Account Econ 3:73–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hribar P, Jenkins NT (2004) The effect of accounting restatements on earnings revisions and the estimated cost of capital. Rev Acc Stud 9:337–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutton A, Marcus A, Tehranian H (2009) Opaque financial reports, R2, and crash risk. J Financ Econ 94:67–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kinney WR, McDaniel LS (1989) Characteristics of firms correcting previously reported quarterly earnings. J Account Econ 11:71–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwak W, Lee HY, Eldridge SW (2009) Institutional ownership and income smoothing by Japanese banks through loan loss provisions. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 12:219–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SW, Mullineaux DJ (2004) Monitoring, financial distress, and the structure of commercial lending syndicates. Financ Manage 33:107–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Leftwich R (1981) Evidence of the impact of mandatory changes in accounting principles on corporate loan agreements. J Account Econ 3:3–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manso G, Strulovici B, Tchistyi A (2010) Performance-sensitive debt. Rev Financ Stud 23:1819–1854

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskara PK, Mullineaux DJ (2011) Information asymmetry and self-selection bias in bank loan announcement studies. J Financ Econ 101:684–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNichols MF (2002) The quality of accruals and earnings: the role of accrual estimation errors: discussion. Account Rev 77:61–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen D, Puri TN (2014) Information asymmetry and accounting restatement: NYSE-AMEX and NASDAQ evidence. Rev Quant Financ Acc 43:211–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmrose Z-V, Scholz S (2004) The circumstances and legal consequences of non-GAAP reporting: evidence from restatements. Contemp Account Res 21:139–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmrose Z-V, Richardson VJ, Scholz S (2004) Determinants of market reactions to restatement announcements. J Account Econ 37:59–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen M, Rajan R (1994) The benefits of lending relationships: evidence from small business data. J Financ 49:3–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG (1992) Insiders and outsiders: The choice between informed and arm’s-length debt. J Financ 1367–1400

  • Roberts M, Sufi A (2009) Renegotiation of financial contracts: evidence from private credit agreements. J Financ Econ 93:159–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roychowdhury S (2006) Earnings management through real activities manipulation. J Account Econ 42:335–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarkar S, Zhang C (2015) Loan-commitment borrowing and performance-sensitive debt, Rev Quant Financ Account. Forthcoming

  • Stumpp P (2000) Putting EBITDA in perspective. Ten critical failings of EBITDA as the principal determinant of cash flow. Moody’s Investors Service. Global Credit Research. Special Comment

  • Sufi A (2007) Information asymmetry and financing arrangements: evidence from syndicated loans. J Financ 62:629–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sufi A (2009) Bank lines of credit in corporate finance: an empirical analysis. Rev Financ Stud 22:1057–1088

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweeney AP (1994) Debt-Covenant violations and managers’ accounting responses. J Account Econ 17:281–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tchistyi A (2013) Security design with correlated hidden cash flows: The optimality of performance pricing. University of California Berkeley Working Paper

  • Tchistyi A, Yermack D, Yun H (2011) Negative hedging: performance-sensitive debt and CEOs’ equity incentives. J Financ Quant Anal 46:657–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vesala T (2007) Switching costs and relationship profits in bank lending. J Bank Financ 31:477–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watts RL, Zimmerman JL (1978) Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards. Account Rev 53:112–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Watts RL, Zimmerman JL (1990) Positive accounting theory: a ten year perspective. Account Rev 65:131–156

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Yan Hu is grateful to the financial support from University of Minnesota Grant-in-Aid of Research, Artistry, and Scholarship. We thank Sudipta Basu, Naveen Daniel, Elyas Elyasiani, Lily Li, Xi Li, Jagan Krishnan, Jayanthi Krishnan, Mihir Mehta, Lalitha Naveen, David Reeb, Ryan Williams, and seminar participants at Temple University, University of Minnesota, Duluth, and the 2010 FMA Annual Meeting in New York for their helpful comments and discussions. All errors are solely ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yan Hu.

Appendix: Variable definitions

Appendix: Variable definitions

Variable

Definition

Performance pricing type

Debt to EBITDA

Outstanding debt divided by (net income plus depreciation and other non-cash charges)

Senior Rating

Rating of outstanding debt on a senior basis

Leverage ratio

Debt divided by capitalization (or equity)

Senior Debt to EBITDA

Outstanding debt on a senior basis divided by (net income plus depreciation and other non-cash charges)

Fixed Charge Coverage

Equal to EBITDA divided by (interest charges paid plus long-term lease payments)

Debt to Tangible Net Worth

Total debt divided by (net worth minus intangible assets)

Interest Coverage

Equal to EBITDA divided by interest expense

Debt Service Coverage

Equal to EBITDA divided by (interest expense plus the quantity of principal repayments)

Loan characteristics

Ln(loan size)

Natural logarithm of loan amount in US dollars

Maturity

Time to maturity of the loan in years

Revolver

Dummy = 1 if the loan is a revolver (364-Day Loan, Revolver/Line < 1 Yr., Revolver/Line > = 1 Yr., Revolver/Term Loan)

Secured

Dummy = 1 if the loan is secured

Senior

Dummy = 1 if the loan is senior

Covenant

Dummy = 1 if the loan has any financial covenant or general covenant

Syndicate

Dummy = 1 if the loan is syndicated

Borrower characteristics

Firmsize

Natural logarithm of book value of assets

Market-to-book

The sum of market value of equity and book value debt divided by book value of total assets

ROA

Net income divided by total assets

Rating dummy

A dummy variable that equals one if any type of S&P debt rating of a firm is available in Compustat

Tangibility

Net PP&E divided by total assets

Big5

Indicator variable equal one if auditor code (Compustat variable AU) is 01 (Arthur Anderson), 02 (Arthur Young), 03, 04,05,06, 07, or 08

Accounting quality

DD_AQ10

The standard deviation of residuals of following equation over the years t−9 through t:

 

\(CA_{j,t} = c + \varphi_{1} CFO_{j,t - 1} + \, \varphi_{2} CFO_{j,t} + \varphi_{3} CFO_{j,t + 1} + \upsilon_{j,t} .\)

 

All variables are scaled by assets of that year. Estimation of Dechow and Dichev (2002, hereafter DD) model involves two steps. First, we estimate above equation annually for each firm for each of the 10 years t−9 through t. Then we calculate the standard deviation of firm j’s residuals across the 10 years, i.e., υ j,t through υ j,t9

DD_AQ5

The same as DD_AQ10 except that it is the standard deviation of residuals over the 5 years t−4 through t

MDD_AQ10

Following McNichols (2002), we estimate the modified DD model (hereafter MDD) as follows:

 

\(CA_{j,t} = c + \varphi_{1} CFO_{j,t - 1} + \, \varphi_{2} CFO_{j,t} + \varphi_{3} CFO_{j,t + 1} + + \, \varphi_{4} \Delta Sales_{j,t} + + \, \varphi_{5} PPE_{j,t} + \upsilon_{j,t} .\)

 

MDD model is equivalent to the DD model except that changes in sales and PPE are added. All variables are scaled by assets of that year. MDD_AQ10 is the standard deviation of residuals of the above equation over the years t−9 through t. MDD model involves two steps. First, we estimate above equation annually for each of the Fama and French (1997) 48 industry groups having at least 20 firms for each of the 10 years t−9 through t. Then we calculate the standard deviation of firm j’s residuals across the 10 years, i.e., υ j,t through υ j,t9

MDD_AQ5

The same as MDD_AQ10 except that it is the standard deviation of residuals over the 5 years t−4 through t

ADD_AQ10

It is the average of the absolute value of υ j,t through υ j,t9 of DD model

ADD_AQ5

It is the average of the absolute value of υ j,t through υ j,t4 of DD model

AMDD_AQ10

It is the average of the absolute value of υ j,t through υ j,t9 of MDD model

AMDD_AQ5

It is the average of the absolute value of υ j,t through υ j,t4 of MDD model

Abnormal CFO

Following Dechow et al. (1998) and Roychowdhury (2006), we measure abnormal CFO as deviation from the predicted values from the corresponding industry-year regression \(\frac{{CFO_{t} }}{{A_{t - 1} }} = \alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} \frac{1}{{A_{t - 1} }} + \beta_{1} \frac{{S_{t} }}{{A_{t - 1} }} + \beta_{2} \frac{{\Delta S_{t} }}{{A_{t - 1} }} + \varepsilon_{t}\)

Information opacity

Opacity index

Opacity index based on Anderson, Duru and Reeb (2008). It is an index based on four individual proxies: trading volume, bid-ask spread, analyst following and analyst forecast errors. Each of the four variables is ranked into deciles, with the most opaque firm taking a value of 10 and the least one taking a value of 1. The four ranks are summed and divided by 40

Trading volume

Natural logarithm of the average daily dollar volume during a fiscal year

Bid-ask spread

The difference of ask price and bid price divided by the average of bid and ask prices

# of analysts

The number of analysts providing EPS fiscal year-end estimate three quarters before the end of fiscal year

Forecast error

The absolute value of the difference between the mean analysts’ EPS forecast (EPS fiscal year-end estimate provided three quarters before the end of fiscal year) and actual EPS scaled by the firm’s stock price

Syndicate concentration

Sum of square of lead bank shares or sum of square of 100 divided by the number of lead banks if lead bank share data are missing

Lead bank share

The largest share of lead bank in a particular loan or 100 divided by the number of lead banks if lead bank share data are missing

Strength of bank-borrower relationship

Strength of lead bank-borrower prior lending relation ($)

It is computed as the dollar amount of loans arranged by a particular lead bank and its predecessors for a firm during the previous 5 years divided by the total dollar amount of loans borrowed by the firm during the same period

Strength of lead bank-borrower prior lending relation (N)

It is computed as the number of loans arranged by a particular lead bank and its predecessors for a firm during the previous 5 years divided by the total number of loans borrowed by the firm during the same period

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hu, Y., Mao, C. Accounting quality, bank monitoring, and performance pricing loans. Rev Quant Finan Acc 49, 569–597 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0601-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0601-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation