Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Do the Location, Size and Budget of Open Space Conservation Affect Land Values?

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this article we present a model to examine the optimal location, size, and budget of open space conservation and the resulting impact on land values and local fiscal conditions in an urban area. Results indicate that open space conservation can transform the defining features of an urban landscape. A well-designed open space conservation program can improve municipal services, increase total property values, and attract households to the city without substantially increasing tax burdens, while an improperly designed open space program can have the opposite effects. Results also reveal the key parameters that determine the optimal location and size of open space conservation and their fiscal and land value effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The assumption μ < 1 is made to ensure that some public services will be provided when they are non-rival public goods (see proposition 1 below).

  2. This number is consistent with the USDA statistics about farmland value. Please see “Land Values and Cash Rents 2007 Summary,” available at http://economics.ag.utk.edu/extension/forage/AgriLandVa-08-03-2007.pdf.

  3. For example, Metro Boston has a diameter of approximately 50 miles (from Duxbury, MA to Bedford, MA); Metro Portland Oregon has a diameter of approximately 26 miles (from Wilsonville, OR to Vancouver, WA).

  4. The simulations assume that open space is purchased at the prevailing market prices before the open space conservation.

  5. The property tax rate is calculated as the rate relative to other user costs of home ownership, which is around 10 % depending on the household’s income (Poterba 1991). Thus, the un-normalized property tax rate is between 0.72 and 1.04 %.

  6. Kopits et al. (2007) examine the tradeoff between private lots and public open space in subdivisions at the urban–rural fringe. They find that households do not value public open space nearly as much as a larger lot. Thus, reducing private acreage to provide more public subdivision open space tends to lead to overall reductions in housing values. More recently, Abbott and Klaiber (2010) find that the interactions between subdivision open space and private open space in the form of lot size change from complementarity at small scales to substitutability at large scales. This paper does not directly model the interactions. However, public open space can affect private lot sizes through its effect on land prices in our model. Because open space conservation tends to increase land prices nearby, it tends to reduce lot sizes in those areas. On the other hand, open space conservation may reduce land prices in areas located farther away because households located in those areas may benefit little from open space amenities, but must pay a higher property tax rate. Thus, open space conservation may lead to larger lot sizes in areas located farther away.

References

  • Abbott, J. K., & Klaiber, H. A. (2010). Is all space created equal? Uncovering the relationship between competing land uses in subdivisions. Ecological Economics, 70(2), 296–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, G., & Bennett, L. L. (2001). Valuing open space and land-use patterns in urban watersheds. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22(2–3), 221–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. T., & West, S. E. (2006). Open space, residential property values, and spatial context. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 773–789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding, T. E., & Deacon, R. T. (1972). The demand for the services of non-federal governments. American Economic Review, 62(5), 891–901.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carruthers, J. I., & Úlfarsson, G. F. (2008). Does ‘smart growth’ matter to public finance? Urban Studies, 45, 1791–1823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheshire, P. C., & Sheppard, S. C. (1995). On the price of land and the value of amenities. Economica, 62(246), 247–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheshire, P. C., & Sheppard, S. C. (2002). The welfare economics of land use planning. Journal of Urban Economics, 52(2), 242–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geoghegan, J. (2002). The value of open spaces in residential land use. Land Use Policy, 19(1), 91–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geoghegan, J., Lynch, L., & Bucholtz, S. (2003). Capitalization of open spaces into housing values and the residential property tax revenue impacts of agricultural easement programs. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, 32(1), 33–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, E. (2002). The effects of open space on residential property value. Land Economics, 78(4), 465–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, E. G., & Bockstael, N. E. (2001). The problem of identifying land use spillovers: measuring the effects of open space on residential property values. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(3), 698–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klaiber, H. A., & Phaneuf, D. J. (2010). Valuing open space in a residential sorting model of the twin cities. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 60(2), 57–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopits, E., McConnell, V., & Walls, M. (2007). The tradeoff between private lots and public open space in subdivisions at the urban–rural fringe. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89(5), 1191–1197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C. M., & Fujita, M. (1997). Efficient configuration of a greenbelt: theoretical modelling of greenbelt amenity. Environment & Planning A, 29(11), 1999–2017.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (1976). Amenities and property values in a model of an urban area. Journal of Public Economics, 5(1–2), 119–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. (1984). Tax subsidies to owner-occupied housing: an asset-market approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99(4), 729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. (1991). House price dynamics: the role of tax policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 22(2), 143–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trust for Public Land. (2014). LandVote® https://tpl.quickbase.com/db/bbqna2qct?a=dbpage&pageID=8. Accessed July 25, 2014.

  • U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2014). The 2011 consumer expenditure survey. Washington: U.S. Department of Labor.

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Forest Service. (2014). Open space conservation. http://www.fs.fed.us/openspace/. Accessed August 31, 2014.

  • Walsh, R. (2007). Endogenous open space amenities in a locational equilibrium. Journal of Urban Economics, 61(2), 319–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J. (2006). Environmental amenities, urban sprawl, and community characteristics. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 52(2), 527–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J. (2010). Economic fundamentals and urban-suburban disparities. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 570–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J. (2014). Public open space conservation under a budget constraint. Journal of Public Economics, 111, 96–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J., & Plantinga, A. J. (2003). The influence of public open space on urban spatial structure. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46(2), 288–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yinger, J. (1982). Capitalization and the theory of local public finance. The Journal of Political Economy, 90(5), 917–943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments. This paper is based on work supported by the U.S. Department of Agriculture Forest Service Pacific Northwest Research Station JVA 11-JV-11261985-073, and by the U.S. Department of Agriculture National Institute of Food and Agriculture under Award No. 2012-70002-19388. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of their home institutions or the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to JunJie Wu.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

When households have homogeneous preferences, the maximization problem (6) can be simplified to

$$ \underset{\left(\tau, g\right)}{Max}\kern1em \frac{g^{\mu }}{c+\tau}\kern0.37em \mathrm{s}.\ \mathrm{t}.\kern0.5em T{C}_s+T{C}_o\le TR. $$

Substituting Eq. (1) into Eqs. (2)–(4), the total tax revenue and the total costs of municipal services and open space conservation can be written as:

$$ TR=\frac{\tau {g}^{\mu }}{\left(c+\tau \right)}{\displaystyle \underset{D-S}{\iint }A{\left[y\left(u,v\right)-tx\right]}^{\beta_i}a{\left(u,v;S\right)}^{\gamma_i} dudv}\equiv \frac{\tau {g}^{\mu }}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\tilde{R}, $$
(A1)
$$ T{C}_s=g{N}^{\lambda }={g}^{1+\lambda \mu \delta }{\left[{\displaystyle \underset{D-S}{\iint }{A}^{\delta }{\left[y\left(u,v\right)-tx\right]}^{\beta_i\delta }a{\left(u,v;S\right)}^{\gamma_i\delta } dudv}\right]}^{\lambda}\equiv {g}^{1+\lambda \mu \delta }{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda }, $$
(A2)
$$ T{C}_o=\frac{c{g}^{\mu }}{\left(c+\tau \right)}{\displaystyle \underset{S}{\iint }A{\left[y\left(u,v\right)-tx\right]}^{\beta_i}a{\left(u,v;S\right)}^{\gamma_i} dudv}\equiv \frac{c{g}^{\mu }}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\tilde{G}, $$
(A3)

where y(u, v) denotes the income of the household located at (u, v). Using (A1)–(A3), the city’s budget constraint can be written as:

$$ \frac{c{g}^{\mu }}{c+\tau}\le \frac{M(g)}{\tilde{R}+\tilde{G}}, $$
(A4)

where \( M(g)\equiv {g}^{\mu}\tilde{R}-{g}^{1+\lambda \mu \delta }{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda } \). At the optimum, the constraint must hold with equality; otherwise, a smaller τexists that satisfies the budget constraint and improves the objective function. Substituting (A4) into the objective function, the maximization problem (5) can be transformed to

$$ \underset{\left(\tau, g\right)}{Max}\ \frac{M(g)}{\tilde{R}+\tilde{G}}, $$
(A5)

with τ being determined by the budget constraint that holds with equality. Note that M(g) is a concave function and reaches its maximum at

$$ {g}^{\ast }={\left[\frac{\mu \tilde{R}}{\left(1+\lambda \mu \delta \right){\tilde{N}}^{\lambda }}\right]}^{\frac{1}{1-\left(1-\lambda \delta \right)\mu }}, $$
(A6)

which gives Eq. (8).

Thus, if \( \overline{G}<M\left({g}^{\ast}\right) \), τ * defined by the budget constraint at g* is positive, and (τ , g ) is the optimal solution of (A1). Substituting g* into the budget constraint and solving for τ, we obtain:

$$ {\tau}^{\ast }=\frac{c\left(1+\lambda \mu \delta \right)}{1-\left(1-\lambda \delta \right)\mu}\left(1+\frac{\tilde{G}}{\tilde{R}}\right)-c. $$
(A7)

By definition,

$$ 1-\rho =\frac{T{C}_o}{TR}=\frac{c\tilde{G}}{\tau \tilde{R}}\Rightarrow \kern0.5em \frac{\tilde{G}}{\tilde{R}}=\left(1-\rho \right)\frac{\tau }{c} $$
(A8)

Substituting (A8) into (A7) and solving for τ, we obtain Eq. (6).

If \( \overline{G}<M\left({g}^{\ast}\right),{\tau}^{\ast } \) defined by the budget constraint at g* is positive, and (τ , g ) is the optimal solution of (A5). If \( \overline{G}\ge M\left({g}^{\ast}\right) \), no (τ, g) combination would satisfy the budget constraint, and (A5) has no solution.

Proof of Corollary 1

Differentiating \( \log \left(\tilde{G}/\tilde{R}\right) \) with respect to S (i.e., expanding the boundary S parallally to all directions by an infinitesimal amount) gives:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{d}{dS} \log \left(\frac{\tilde{G}}{\tilde{R}}\right)=\frac{1}{\tilde{G}}\left[{\left.\frac{\partial \tilde{G}}{\partial S}\right|}_a+{\displaystyle \underset{S}{\iint }A{\left(y-tx\right)}^{\beta_i}\gamma {a}^{\gamma_i}\frac{\partial a}{\partial S} dudv}\right]\hfill \\ {}\kern5em -\frac{1}{\tilde{R}}\left[{\left.\frac{\partial \tilde{R}}{\partial S}\right|}_a+{\displaystyle \underset{D-S}{\iint }A{\left(y-tx\right)}^{\beta_i}\gamma {a}^{\gamma_i}\frac{\partial a}{\partial S} dudv}\right]\hfill \\ {}\kern5em =\left[{\varepsilon}_S^G+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]-\left[-{\varepsilon}_S^R+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]\hfill \\ {}\kern5em ={\varepsilon}_S^G+{\varepsilon}_S^R\ge 0\hfill \end{array}. $$
(A9)

Likewise, differentiating \( \log \left(\tilde{R}/{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda}\right) \) with respect to S gives

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{d}{dS} \log \left(\frac{\tilde{R}}{{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda }}\right)=\left[-{\varepsilon}_S^R+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]-\lambda \left[-{\varepsilon}_S^N+\gamma \delta {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]\hfill \\ {}\kern6em =\left(\lambda {\varepsilon}_S^N-{\varepsilon}_S^R\right)+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\left(1-\lambda \delta \right)\hfill \end{array}, $$
(A10)

which is greater than or equal to zero if and only if (13) holds.

Proof of Corollary 2

Differentiating \( \log \left({\tilde{R}}^{1+\lambda \delta \mu }/{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda \mu}\right) \) with respect to S, we obtain:

$$ \begin{array}{c}\hfill \frac{d}{dS} \log \left(\frac{{\tilde{R}}^{1+\lambda \delta \mu }}{{\tilde{N}}^{\lambda \mu }}\right)=\left(1+\lambda \delta \mu \right)\left[-{\varepsilon}_S^R+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]-\lambda \mu \left[-{\varepsilon}_S^N+\gamma \delta {\varepsilon}_S^a\right]\hfill \\ {}\hfill =\left[\lambda \mu {\varepsilon}_S^N-\left(1+\lambda \delta \mu \right){\varepsilon}_S^R\right]+\gamma {\varepsilon}_S^a\hfill \end{array} $$
(A11)

which is non-negative if and only if (15) holds.

Proof of Proposition 2

Suppose the high-income households are the majority in the city. The maximization problem (6) can be written as

$$ \underset{\left(\tau, g\right)}{Max}\kern0.5em \frac{g^{\mu_h}}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\kern0.75em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.\kern0.5em \frac{M(g)-\overline{G}}{\left({\tilde{R}}_l{g}^{\mu_l}+{\tilde{R}}_h{g}^{\mu_h}\right)}\ge \frac{1}{c+\tau }, $$
(A12)

where \( M(g)=\left({\tilde{R}}_l{g}^{\mu_l}+{\tilde{R}}_h{g}^{\mu_h}\right)-g{\left({\tilde{N}}_l{g}^{\mu_l}+{\tilde{N}}_h{g}^{\mu_h}\right)}^{\lambda }. \) At the optimum, the constraint must hold with equality. Substituting the budget constraint into the objective function, the maximization problem can be transformed to

$$ \underset{\left(\tau, g\right)}{Max}\ \frac{M(g)-\overline{G}}{\widehat{R}(g)}\kern0.75em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.\kern0.5em \frac{M(g)-\overline{G}}{g^{\mu_h}\widehat{R}(g)}=\frac{1}{c+\tau }, $$
(A13)

where \( \tilde{R}(g)=\left({\tilde{R}}_l{g}^{\mu_l-{\mu}_h}+{\tilde{R}}_h\right) \). Note that the objective function is continuous and bounded in \( \left[0,\overline{g}\right] \), where \( \overline{g} \) is the largest g defined by \( M\left(\overline{g}\right)=0 \), beyond which M(g) < 0. Thus, the objective function has a globe maximum in \( \left[0,\overline{g}\right] \). Denote the maximum point by g* and G M(g ). If \( \overline{G}<M\left({g}^{\ast}\right) \), τ defined by the budget constraint at gi is positive, and (τ , g ) is the optimal solution of (A13).

Denote the solution of (A13) by (τ i , g i ) when income group i is the majority. (τ h , g h ) is indeed the majority group if and only if

$$ {N}_h^{\ast}\left({\tau}_h^{\ast },{g}_h^{\ast}\right)\ge {N}_l^{\ast}\left({\tau}_h^{\ast },{g}_h^{\ast}\right). $$
(A14)

Likewise, (τ l , g l ), is indeed the majority group if and only if

$$ {N}_l^{\ast}\left({\tau}_l^{\ast },{g}_l^{\ast}\right)\ge {N}_h^{\ast}\left({\tau}_l^{\ast },{g}_l^{\ast}\right). $$
(A15)

We now prove that either (A14) or (A15) must hold. If (A14) does not hold, then N h (τ h , g h ) < N l (τ h , g h ). In this case, (A15) must hold because N h (τ l , g l ) ≤ N h (τ h , g h ) < N l (τ h , g h ) ≤ N l (τ l , g l ) . Similarly, we can prove that if (A15) does not hold, (A14) must hold. This proves that a majority equilibrium must exist in the city if \( \overline{G}<M\left({g}^{\ast}\right) \).

To derive the equilibrium property tax rate, we use the transformation \( g={\left[u\left(c+\tau \right)\right]}^{1/{\mu}_h} \) and τ = τ to transform the maximization problem (A13) into:

$$ \underset{\left(\tau, u\right)}{ \max}\kern1em u\kern0.5em \mathrm{s}.\mathrm{t}.\kern0.5em T{C}_s+\overline{G}=T{R}_h+T{R}_l. $$
(A16)

where

$$ T{C}_s=g{\left({N}_l+{N}_h\right)}^{\lambda }={\left(c+\tau \right)}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}}{u}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}}{\left({N}_h+{N}_l\right)}^{\lambda }, $$
(A17)
$$ {N}_h={\left[\left(c+\tau \right)u\right]}^{\delta }{\tilde{N}}_h,\kern0.5em {N}_l={\left(c+\tau \right)}^{\frac{\delta {\mu}_l}{\mu_h}}{u}^{\frac{\delta {\mu}_l}{\mu_h}}{\tilde{N}}_l, $$
(A18)
$$ T{R}_h=\tau u{\tilde{R}}_h,\kern1em T{R}_l={\left(c+\tau \right)}^{\frac{\mu_l-{\mu}_h}{\mu_h}}{u}^{\frac{\mu_l}{\mu_h}}{\tilde{R}}_l, $$
(A19)

The Lagrangian function for the maximization problem is

$$ L\left(\tau, u\right)=u+\xi \left[T{R}_h+T{R}_l-T{C}_s-T{C}_o\right]. $$
(A20)

Where ξ is the Lagarangian multiplier. Differentiating (A20) with respect to τ and setting it equal zero, we obtain the following first-order condition:

$$ \frac{\partial L}{\partial \tau }=0\Rightarrow \frac{\partial T{C}_s}{\partial \tau }=\frac{\partial T{R}_h}{\partial \tau }+\frac{\partial T{R}_l}{\partial \tau }. $$
(A21)

Assume household Differentiating (A17) with respect to τ and using (A18) gives

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial T{C}_s}{\partial \tau }=\frac{1}{\mu_h}{\left(c+\tau \right)}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}-1}{u}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}}{\left({N}_h+{N}_l\right)}^{\lambda }+{\left(c+\tau \right)}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}}{u}^{\frac{1}{\mu_h}}\lambda {\left({N}_h+{N}_l\right)}^{\lambda -1}\left(\frac{\partial {N}_h}{d\tau }+\frac{\partial {N}_l}{d\tau}\right)\hfill \\ {}\kern2.5em =\frac{T{C}_s}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\frac{1}{\mu_h}+\frac{\lambda T{C}_s}{N}\left(\frac{\partial {N}_h}{\partial \tau }+\frac{\partial {N}_l}{\partial \tau}\right)\hfill \end{array}. $$
(A22)

Differentiating (A10) with respect to τ and substituting the results into (A22), we obtain

$$ \frac{\partial T{C}_s}{\partial \tau }=\frac{T{C}_s}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\left[\frac{1}{\mu_h}+\frac{\lambda \delta }{N}\left({N}_h+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}}{\mu_h}{N}_l\right)\right]. $$
(A23)

Differentiating (A19) with respect to τ gives

$$ \frac{\partial T{R}_h}{\partial \tau }=\frac{T{R}_h}{\tau } $$
(A24)
$$ \frac{\partial T{R}_l}{\partial \tau }=\frac{T{R}_l}{\tau }+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}-{\mu}_h}{\mu_h}\frac{T{R}_l}{\left(c+\tau \right)} $$
(A25)

Substituting (A23)–(A25) into (A21) and noting TR = TR h  + TR l and TC s  + TC o  = TR gives

$$ \frac{T{C}_s}{\left(c+\tau \right)}\left[\frac{1}{\mu_h}+\frac{\lambda \delta }{N}\left(N-{N}_l+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}}{\mu_h}{N}_l\right)\right]=\frac{TR}{\tau }+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}-{\mu}_h}{\mu_h}\frac{T{R}_l}{\left(1+\tau \right)} $$
(A26)
$$ \rho \left[\frac{1}{\mu_h}+\lambda \delta \left(1+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}-{\mu}_h}{\mu_h}{r}_l\right)\right]=\frac{\left(1+\tau \right)}{\tau }+\frac{\mu_{{}_l}-{\mu}_h}{\mu_h}{m}_l, $$
(A27)

where ρ = TC s /TR, r l  = N l /N, m l  = TR s /TR. Solving (A27) for τ gives (18). The result for the case where low-income households are the majority can be similarly derived.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, J., Xu, W. & Alig, R.J. How Do the Location, Size and Budget of Open Space Conservation Affect Land Values?. J Real Estate Finan Econ 52, 73–97 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9506-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-015-9506-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation