Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

School district consolidation policies: endogenous cost inefficiency and saving reversals

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Some education policy studies suggest that consolidation of public school districts saves resources. However, endogeneity in cost models would result in incorrect estimates of the effects of consolidation. We use a new stochastic frontier methodology to examine district expenditures while handling endogeneity. Using the data from California, we find that the effects of student achievement and education market concentration on expenditure per pupil are substantially larger when endogeneity is handled. Our findings are robust to concerns such as instrumental variable adequacy and spatial interactions. Our consolidation simulations indicate that failure to address endogeneity can result in unrealistic expectations of savings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For details, see the expenditure reports of the Institute of Education Sciences (IES).

  2. Even for the use of restricted funds, there is little or no formal accountability, and as explained by Timar (2006), some districts even acknowledge that they spend the restricted categorical funds for general-purpose use.

  3. Reduced regulation may result in efficiency variation depending on the type of intervention and market structure. See Grosskopf et al. (2009), Gronberg et al. (2012), and Gronberg et al. (2015) for examples.

  4. This statement rules out the entire literature of stochastic frontier analysis, which is acknowledged by strands of studies. A detailed defense of this literature is beyond the scope of our study.

  5. We modify the Cobb–Douglas form by adding the square of enrollment to allow testing the economies of size and the shape of the cost function.

  6. Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003) provide an extensive survey of traditional stochastic frontier models.

  7. See Wang and Schmidt (2002).

  8. See Duygun et al. (2016) and Kutlu (2017) for recent variations and extensions of this model.

  9. Historically, Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017) is the first paper (2013) that introduced endogenous environmental variables and endogeneity test in the maximum likelihood estimation setting to our knowledge. Amsler et al. (2017) is a recent paper that allows endogenous environmental variables, too.

  10. We programmed the analysis in this section using Stata 13 and MATLAB 2014a. The programs and the Stata ado files are available upon request. The Stata command is also available on the Statistical Software Components (SSC) at Boston College, and on the Stata repository (package st0466). For more information about this Stata module, see Karakaplan (2017) or type the following command in Stata: findit sfkk.

  11. See their Sect. 4.2 for the moment conditions and Sect. 4.3 for specific comments on Kutlu (2010) and Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017).

  12. The details about the assumptions and how the estimator is derived are available in Kutlu (2010) and Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017).

  13. See Kutlu (2010) and Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017) for further details.

  14. The violation of this assumption may bias efficiency estimates. A generalization of true fixed effects model of Greene (2005a, b) to the endogeneity case as done by Kutlu et al. (2017) may overcome such difficulties in the panel data context.

  15. For statistical and financial purposes, California Department of Education began classifying County Offices of Education, California Education Authority School District, state schools for disabilities, and state charter schools as school districts in 2004. Structurally, however, these institutions are considerably different than traditional elementary, high, and unified public school districts. For example, County Offices of Education provide complementary and supplementary services, staff development, technical assistance, legal and financial advice, curriculum and instructional support to the public school districts. To give another example, Regional Occupational Centers/Programs provide career education, development, and workforce preparation by operating through Joint Powers Agreements (JPA) with traditional school districts, or through County Boards of Education. Without taking such structural differences into account, many print and online sources count these institutions as public school districts due to the change in the classification and report that the number of public school districts in California is more than 1000. Our data set, on the other hand, shows that the number of traditional public school districts in the 2010–2011 school year is 935. Our sample size drops from 935 to 913 due to the unavailability of some of the observations mostly in the student achievement data.

  16. The CWI data are available for all states at http://bush.tamu.edu/research/faculty/Taylor_CWI/.

  17. Even in the age of the Internet, there are Internet costs and shipping costs, which are the counterpart of transportation cost. Since the warehouses of online shops and the hubs of package delivery companies are in central locations, shipping costs for transporting the items to remote locations would be more than transporting them to central locations. In addition, a policy brief of the Rural School and Community Trust by Hobbs (2004) explains how newer education technologies are much more expensive in rural areas. Also, the report indicates that maintenance and technical assistance for these technologies are costlier in remote locations.

  18. We do not control for the percentage middle school students since variation in this variable is low.

  19. The source of these data is demographics from Census 2010.

  20. The source of data is the US Geological Survey (USGS) Geographic Names Information System (GNIS).

  21. The correlation between the proxy for material costs and the number of springs is \(-0.0879\). This outcome would indicate that our material cost/geographic isolation proxy variable is not necessarily correlated with the number of springs topography measure. While the fact that material costs measure is uncorrelated with the springs variable does not necessarily indicate that the measurement error is not correlated with this IV, such a correlation is highly unlikely.

  22. Note that for Model EX, \(\sigma _w^2 =\sigma _v^2 \).

  23. Expenditure variable in our paper aggregates what needs to be spent for variables that other researchers find to be effective to get more quality.

  24. As explained by Karakaplan and Kutlu (2017), estimations with this model are done in a single stage. So, to avoid confusion, we do not use the name “first-stage statistics” and, instead, call them prediction equations.

  25. Our simulation results confirm the possibility of such large biases.

  26. We calculate ln(district API) corresponding to 10% above the average API as ln(1.1 \(\times \) exp(6.664)) = 6.760.

  27. Such a change in a district’s HHI is not necessarily an outcome of a change in the enrollment of the district. The chance in a district’s HHI can solely be a result of changes in the enrollments of other districts in the district’s education market.

  28. We can include only a single bias correction term for enrollment variable and its squared term. Intuitively, this is because the squared enrollment term is a function of enrollment, and conditional on enrollment, these two variables are exogenous. This may be seen from the decomposition of the log likelihood \(\hbox {ln}L\left( \theta \right) =\hbox {ln}L_{y|x} \left( \theta \right) +\hbox {ln}L_x \left( \theta \right) \). In the standard instrumental variable approaches such as 2SLS, a prediction equation for each function of an endogenous variable would be needed. In our setting, however, we need a prediction equation only for the original endogenous variable but not for its functions. For more details regarding this issue, see Wooldridge (2010) and Amsler et al. (2016).

  29. See Grosskopf et al. (2001), Imazeki and Reschovsky (2004), Gronberg et al. (2015), and others.

  30. These findings are available upon request.

  31. It is important to note that Table 6 includes only two extended versions of Model EN in Table 3. Model EXs are excluded from Table 6, but available upon request. Assuming that Model EN in Table 3 is the null model, Extended Model EN-1 as an alternative model has a significantly better fit and Extended Model EN-2 has an even better fit than Extended Model EN-1 according to the likelihood ratio test.

  32. School districts have different numbers of criteria to be met depending on the applicability of the criteria.

  33. While the education market areas are larger for each district with the HHI-R15 measure, HHI-R15 of a district can be larger or smaller than, or equal to the HHI measure of that district depending on how much the enrollment and the number of districts in the district’s education market change with the increase in the education market area. In our sample, HHI of 723 districts is larger than their HHI-R15 and 166 districts have smaller HHI than their HHI-R15. HHI of 24 districts is equal to their HHI-R15.

  34. The regression results with 20-mile and 30-mile radii approaches are in line with the results in Table 8, so we omitted them.

  35. CBSAs are identified by the Office of Management and Budget. A metropolitan area contains a core urban population of 50,000 or more, and a micropolitan area contains an urban core population of more than 10,000 but less than 50,000. Each metropolitan or micropolitan area contains counties with the core urban areas and any neighboring counties with a high degree of social and economic integration with the urban core. If a county does not belong to a metropolitan or micropolitan area, then we take that county as a separate educational market.

  36. CDE assigns each cross-county school district to a single county. To determine the locations of public school districts, we use that designation. We get the location and enrollment data of private schools from the National Center for Education Statistics (NCES) Private School Universe Survey (PSS).

  37. California State is known to be carrying out various consolidation projects in the past that the number of traditional public school districts decreased from more than 2,000 to less than 1,000 in fifty years.

  38. Using only the regression subsample is an alternative economic simulation approach. However, our findings indicate that excluding the 22 school districts with missing observations from the analysis does not change the results qualitatively.

  39. There is not any strong factual evidence against this assumption, and families do not have many incentives to move solely due to a consolidation decision of a district, at least not within the first year of consolidation during when the overall consequences of consolidation would be ambiguous to the public. If we relax this assumption, and if families expect that the consolidated district will be worse than their current district, they would move to other districts, or if they are already in other districts, they would not move to the consolidated district. That would decrease the education market share of the consolidated district compared to the sum of pre-consolidation market shares of the consolidated districts and decrease the resources that were available to them to spend. In this case, education market concentration would not increase as much as it would if parents do not move. So, the cost inefficiency of the consolidated district would not be as big as it would be if parents do not move.

  40. In 2010, California has 90 “very small” districts which has less than 100 students. The decrease in the total number of districts is less than 90 because some very small districts have another very small district in the neighborhood so that they merge and form a district with more than 100 students by eliminating two very small districts at the same time.

  41. This assumption is in line with the assumption that parents do not move as an immediate reaction to the consolidation decision of districts. As explained in Footnote 39, we do not have any substantial real-life evidence for students’ changing schools as a response to accommodate the consolidation of traditional school districts.

  42. Median HHI before consolidation is 0.194, and the average HHI of the districts more than or equal to 100 students is 0.240 before consolidation. These numbers are smaller than 0.249 as expected.

  43. Since price index is a proxy based on linear remoteness of a district from the nearest major metropolitan area, the linear average of the price indices from the two consolidation districts is a suitable proxy for the new district.

  44. By efficient cost, we mean the cost when there is no inefficiency.

References

  • Adetutu M, Glass AJ, Kenjegalieva K, Sickles RC (2014) The effects of efficiency and TFP growth on pollution in Europe: a multistage spatial analysis. J Prod Anal 43:307–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aigner DJ, Lovell CAK, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models. J Econom 6:21–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2016) Endogenous stochastic frontier models. J Econom 190:280–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2017) Endogenous environmental variables in stochastic frontier models. J Econom. http://hdl.handle.net/2123/16763

  • Andrews M, Duncombe W, Yinger J (2002) Revisiting economies of size in American education: Are we any closer to a consensus? Econ Educ Rev 21:245–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belfield CR, Levin HM (2002) The effects of competition between schools on educational outcomes: a review for the United States. Rev Educ Res 72:279–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borland MV, Howsen RM (1992) Student academic achievement and the degree of market concentration in education. Econ Educ Rev 11:31–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornwell C, Schmidt P, Sickles RC (1990) Production frontiers with cross-sectional and time-series variation in efficiency levels. J Econom 46:185–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costrell R, Hanushek E, Loeb S (2008) What do cost functions tell us about the cost of an adequate education? Peabody J Educ 83:198–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dodson ME III, Garrett TA (2004) Inefficient education spending in public school districts: A case for consolidation? Contemp Econ Policy 22:270–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Druska V, Horrace WC (2004) Generalized moments estimation for spatial panel data: Indonesian rice farming. Am J Agric Econ 86:185–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncombe W, Miner J, Ruggiero J (1995) Potential cost savings from school district consolidation: a case study of New York. Econ Educ Rev 14:265–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncombe W, Yinger J (2007) Does school district consolidation cut costs? Educ Finance Policy 2:341–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncombe W, Yinger J (2011) Making do: state constraints and local responses in California’s education finance system. Int Tax Public Finance 18:337–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duygun M, Kutlu L, Sickles RC (2016) Measuring productivity and efficiency: a Kalman filter approach. J Prod Anal 46:155–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fitzpatrick MD, Grissmer D, Hastedt S (2011) What a difference a day makes: estimating daily learning gains during kindergarten and first grade using a natural experiment. Econ Educ Rev 30:269–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fried HO, Lovell CAK, Schmidt SS (2008) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity growth. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Kenjegalieva K, Paez-Farrell J (2013a) Productivity growth decomposition using a spatial autoregressive frontier model. Econ Lett 119:291–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass A, Kenjegalieva K, Sickles RC (2013b) A spatial autoregressive production frontier model for panel data: with an application to european countries. Available at SSRN 2227720

  • Greene W (2005a) Fixed and random effects in stochastic frontier models. J Prod Anal 23:7–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene W (2005b) Reconsidering heterogeneity in panel data estimators of the stochastic frontier model. J Econom 126:269–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1980a) Maximum likelihood estimation of econometric frontier functions. J Econom 3:27–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (1980b) On the estimation of a flexible frontier production model. J Econom 13:101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2003) Simulated likelihood estimation of the normal-gamma stochastic frontier function. J Prod Anal 19:179–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gronberg TJ, Jansen DW, Karakaplan MU, Taylor LL (2015) School district consolidation: market concentration and the scale-efficiency tradeoff. S Econ J 82:580–597

    Google Scholar 

  • Gronberg TJ, Jansen DW, Taylor LL (2011a) The adequacy of educational cost functions: lessons from Texas. Peabody J Educ 86:3–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gronberg TJ, Jansen DW, Taylor LL (2011b) The impact of facilities on the cost of education. Natl Tax J 64:193–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gronberg TJ, Jansen DW, Taylor LL (2012) The relative efficiency of charter schools: a cost frontier approach. Econ Educ Rev 31:302–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosskopf S, Hayes KJ, Taylor LL (2009) The relative efficiency of charter schools. Ann Public Coop Econ 80:67–87. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8292.2008.00381.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosskopf S, Hayes KJ, Taylor LL, Weber WL (2001) On the determinants of school district efficiency: competition and monitoring. J Urban Econ 49:453–478. https://doi.org/10.1006/juec.2000.2201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guan Z, Kumbhakar SC, Myers RJ, Lansink AO (2009) Measuring excess capital capacity in agricultural production. Am J Agric Econ 91:765–776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (2005) The alchemy of ‘costing out’ an adequate education. In: Conference on Adequacy Lawsuits, 2005

  • Hanushek EA (2006) Science violated: spending projections and the ‘costing out’ of an adequate education. Hoover Press, Courting Failure, pp 257–308

  • Hobbs V (2004) The promise and the power of distance learning in rural education. Policy brief. Rural School and Community Trust, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoxby CM (2000) Does competition among public schools benefit students and taxpayers? Am Econ Rev 90:1209–1238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoxby CM (2003) School choice and school productivity: Could school choice be a tide that lifts all boats?. University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Imazeki J, Reschovsky A (2004) Is no child left behind an un (or under) funded federal mandate? Evidence from Texas. Natl Tax J 57:571–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Izadi H, Johnes G, Oskrochi R, Crouchley R (2002) Stochastic frontier estimation of a CES cost function: the case of higher education in Britain. Econ Educ Rev 21:63–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jondrow J, Lovell CAK, Materov IS, Schmidt P (1982) On the estimation of technical inefficiency in the stochastic frontier production function model. J Econom 19:233–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU (2017) Fitting endogenous stochastic frontier models in Stata. Stata J 17:39–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU, Kutlu L (2017) Handling endogeneity in stochastic frontier analysis. Econ Bull 37:889–891

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH, Prucha IR (1999) A generalized moments estimator for the autoregressive parameter in a spatial model. Int Econ Rev 40:509–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Lovell CK (2003) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2010) Battese–Coelli estimator with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 109:79–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2017) A constrained state space approach for estimating firm efficiency. Econ Lett 152:54–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Tran KC, Tsionas MG (2017) A time-varying true individual effects model with endogenous regressors. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2721864

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70:317–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (2012) Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. J Bus Econ Stat 30:67–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marcotte DE, Hemelt SW (2008) Unscheduled school closings and student performance. Educ Finance Policy 3:316–338. https://doi.org/10.1162/edfp.2008.3.3.316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meeusen W, van den Broeck J (1977) Efficiency estimation from Cobb–Douglas production function with composed errors. Int Econ Rev 18:435–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet DL, Collier T (2008) Efficiency in public schools: Does competition matter? J Econom 145:134–157. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2008.05.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mutter RL, Greene WH, Spector W, Rosko MD, Mukamel DB (2013) Investigating the impact of endogeneity on inefficiency estimates in the application of stochastic frontier analysis to nursing homes. J Prod Anal 39:101–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell CJ, Coelli TJ (2005) A bayesian approach to imposing curvature on distance functions. J Econom 126:493–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein J (2007) Does competition among public schools benefit students and taxpayers? Comment Am Econ Rev 97:2026–2037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt P, Sickles RC (1984) Production frontiers and panel data. J Bus Econ Stat 2:367–374

    Google Scholar 

  • Shee A, Stefanou SE (2014) Endogeneity corrected stochastic production frontier and technical efficiency. Am J Agric Econ aau083

  • Stevenson R (1980) Likelihood functions for generalized stochastic frontier functions. J Econom 13:57–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor LL, Fowler Jr WJ (2006) A comparable wage approach to geographic cost adjustment. Research and development report. NCES-2006-321. National Center for Education Statistics

  • Timar T (2006) Financing k-12 education in California. A system overview. Unpublished Manuscript, University of California, Davis

  • Tran KC, Tsionas EG (2013) GMM estimation of stochastic frontier model with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 118:233–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tran KC, Tsionas EG (2015) Endogeneity in stochastic frontier models: Copula approach without external instruments. Econ Lett 133:85–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang H-J, Schmidt P (2002) One-step and two-step estimation of the effects of exogenous variables on technical efficiency levels. J Prod Anal 18:129–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong KK et al (2014) Why is school closed today? Unplanned k-12 school closures in the United States, 2011–2013. PLoS ONE 9:e113755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zanzig BR (1997) Measuring the impact of competition in local government education markets on the cognitive achievement of students. Econ Educ Rev 16:431–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmer T, DeBoer L, Hirth M (2009) Examining economies of scale in school consolidation: assessment of Indiana School Districts. J Educ Finance 35:103–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mustafa U. Karakaplan.

Appendix: Baseline prediction equation estimates for endogenous variables

Appendix: Baseline prediction equation estimates for endogenous variables

Dependent variable: ln(district API)

Constant

6.7887***

(0.0341)

[198.82]

ln(Enrollment)

0.0253***

(0.0066)

[3.83]

\(\hbox {ln(Enrollment)}^{2}\)

\(-\) 0.0013**

(0.0004)

[\(-\) 2.80]

Percent limited English proficiency

\(-\) 0.0545***

(0.0150)

[\(-\) 3.62]

Percent special education students

\(-\) 0.1226**

(0.0463)

[\(-\) 2.65]

Percent high school students

\(-\) 0.1070***

(0.0073)

[\(-\) 14.67]

Percent low-income students

\(-\) 0.2068***

(0.0114)

[\(-\) 18.14]

Price index

\(-\) 0.0412

(0.0313)

[\(-\) 1.32]

Wage index

\(-\) 0.1137*

(0.0486)

[\(-\) 2.34]

Unemployment rate

\(-\) 0.0031***

(0.0007)

[– 4.51]

Number of springs

\(-\) 0.0001***

(0.0000)

[– 4.28]

Observations

913

  1. Standard errors are in parentheses. z-values are in brackets. Asterisks indicate significance at the 0.1% (***), 1% (**), and 5% (*) levels
  2. API is the Academic Performance Index

Dependent variable: HHI

Constant

0.7466***

(0.1113)

[6.71]

ln(Enrollment)

\(-\) 0.1194***

(0.0215)

[\(-\) 5.56]

\(\hbox {ln(Enrollment)}^{2}\)

0.0035*

(0.0015)

[2.42]

Percent limited English proficiency

\(-\) 0.0061

(0.0493)

[\(-\) 0.12]

Percent special education students

\(-\) 0.2189

(0.1507)

[\(-\) 1.45]

Percent high school students

0.0915***

(0.0238)

[3.85]

Percent low-income students

0.1427***

(0.0372)

[3.84]

Price index

\(-\) 0.0252

(0.1020)

[\(-\) 0.25]

Wage index

0.4270**

(0.1587)

[2.69]

Unemployment rate

\(-\) 0.0120***

(0.0025)

[– 4.88]

Number of springs

0.0005***

(0.0001)

[5.78]

Observations

913

  1. Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. z-values are in brackets. Asterisks indicate significance at the 0.1% (***), 1% (**), and 5% (*) levels
  2. HHI is the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Karakaplan, M.U., Kutlu, L. School district consolidation policies: endogenous cost inefficiency and saving reversals. Empir Econ 56, 1729–1768 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1398-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1398-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation